Updated:

The Long-Term Trends of Commodity Prices From 1900 to 2011 Essay

Exclusively available on Available only on IvyPanda® Made by Human No AI

Abstract

This dissertation intends to check the long-term movements of primary commodity price indexes. The data used in this project extends the index introduced by Grilli and Yang (1988) to cover the period from 1900 to 2011. The regression part applies to two-time series called ARMA and ARIMA models. For proper specification of the ARIMA models, we employed unit root tests to determine the order of integration of the data. The results suggest that the ARIMA models chosen provide adequate conditional characterizations of the various commodity price indexes. Commodity prices cannot be perfectly forecasted due to the impact of growth and technology.

Introduction

This dissertation will analyze the commodity price indexes for different periods in the history of worldwide commerce and trade in developing and developed countries. The periods represent years when those basic commodities were traded and bought for either personal or public consumption. The study of commodity price trends demonstrates the flow of supply and demand during the periods. While these laws do not change during the different historical periods, it is also dependent on the practices of commerce and trade during those periods.

The dissertation will focus on the prices of primary commodities from developing countries and manufactured products from developed countries. The dissertation is based on studies on the PS hypothesis and its effects on economic policies. Some economists provided evidence that was argued upon by others by noting the gaps in the indexes.

The results of the indexes do not necessarily give a reflection on how supply and demand affect commodity prices. Consequently, we examined the indexes that provide evidence for the hypothesis of a downward trend in the NBTT despite, the continuous flow and supply of prime commodities. The downward trend affects economies for both developed and developing countries. The literature discusses the factors in the NBTT decline.

Evidence from the literature suggests that the distribution of gains from production affected the long-run trends in the NBTT of trading countries, in both developing to developed countries. The trends influenced the growth of trading activities between producers and consumers in developing countries and developed countries respectively.

In the data analyses, we explored the price indexes of various economic researchers and international agencies and the declining trend of prices of primary commodities from 1900 to 2011. We had a particular interest in the Grilli and Yang’s (1988) index, which was used in the allocation of growth between producers (the developing countries) and consumers (the industrial countries), although their indexes focused on the period 1900 to 1986. The indexes used had gaps at the point of the two world wars but were filled up by Grilli and Yang by way of interpolation.

The renewed interest in the Prebisch-Singer hypothesis is critical due to two factors. First, Grilli and Yang (1988) introduced new computed commodity price indexes which start from 1900 to 1986. The second factor is that the introduction of new methods for analyzing time-series data was a way of reassessing the evidence.

The starting point for Grilli and Yang’s work is their conviction that having high-quality price indexes is essential when testing the PS hypothesis. Using their new commodity index, Grilli and Yang re-estimated the time trend model and found a statistically significant long-term decline in the NBTT that supports the Prebisch-Singer hypothesis. According to this hypothesis that came out of independent studies of Rual Prebisch (1950) and Hans Singer (1950), the prices of primary commodities and manufactured products have a downward trend over a certain period.

The actual and predicted nonfuel commodity terms of trade comparisons for the period 1900-96.
Fig. 1 The actual and predicted nonfuel commodity terms of trade comparisons for the period 1900-96.

The PS hypothesis predicted a decline in the trend of commodities’ terms of trade, which was relatively similar to the actual trend, as shown in figure 1. Grilli and Yang’s (1988) new computation of commodity price indexes triggered the reassessment of the hypothesis evidence.

Over the years, empirical analyses of commodity price trends have proliferated. Few hypotheses in developed economics have not attracted as much attention as the PS hypothesis. Spraos (1980) was among those who rekindled academic interest in the empirical validity of the PS hypothesis in the late 1970s.

In an extension of Spraos’ work, Sapsford (1985) found evidence of discontinuous changes in commodity price data used by Spraos. But Sapsford (1985) found ‘structural instability in Spraos’s work, and argued that the latter’s findings were misleading.

New empirical studies on the PS hypothesis have emerged, and economists continue to debate it. Cuddington and Urzúa (1999) noted that all these studies appeared to have overlooked the significance of the serial correlation shown in the price series. Harry’s Structural Time Series approach requires no preliminary assumptions on the series properties. (Harvey and Todd 1983; Franzini and Havey, 1983; Harvey, 1985; Harvey and Durbin, 1986). Cuddington and Urzúa (1999) re-evaluated the Grilli-Yang index and focused on the requirement that the error processes in the estimated time trend models be stationary.

Perron (1990) has also examined the (MUV-deflated) Grilli-Yang commodity price index (GYCMPI) from 1900 to 1983 for the presence of a unit root. Von Hagen (1989) took a different approach from Cuddington’s and Urzúa’s approaches (1999). Moreover, the literates have analyzed the role of commodity prices in inflation and were outcomes.

This dissertation has four parts. The first part explored the literature focusing on the background, concepts, and meanings of commodity price indexes in the different periods. The second part lists information about the data used in this project. The methodology features the ARMA and ARIMA models and their root tests. The last part is the result of the stationarity of each index, the fitting model for each index, and some forecasts.

The ARMA and ARIMA models appeared in the regression part. An important step was to check the stationarity of the data by applying the unit root test. In selecting the appropriate time series model, it is important to correctly capture the time-series behavior of the data. We employed the Akaike and Schwarz information criteria to assist in determining the correct AR, and MA lag lengths in our time series models.

The stochastic behavior of commodity price plays an important role in evaluating commodity-related projects. There are many aspects of commodity price indexes that were analyzed, for instance, the variance, the skewness, the volatility, the relationship between these indexes with other important economical indexes, and the trend of these indexes during the periods of commerce and trade. The commodity price index tells us the price elasticity of various commodities in different periods, ranging from food to basic needs to raw materials for product manufacturing.

Knowledge of commodity prices and analyzing indexes help policymakers institute policies to pre-empt crisis and deal with the economic crisis. Ordinary citizens should also learn to understand commodity price indexes due to their significance in day-to-day life.

Literature review

Rual Prebisch (1950) and Hans Singer (1950) have independently claimed that several factors would combine to construct a worldly decline in the relevant primary commodity prices in terms of manufactured goods. The factor is known as the PS hypothesis, the subject of several empirical types of research, and has influenced the economic policies of developed and developing countries. The policies aimed at differentiating their productive constructions and export basis away from primary commodities towards manufactured goods, thereby evading the terms of trade deterioration Prebisch and Singer (1950) warned about. The data and methodology sections discuss the factors in the commodities price decline.

Over the years, researchers have provided empirical analyses of commodity price trends based on the PS hypothesis, but many hypotheses in expansion economics have not drawn as much attention as the PS hypothesis. Most of the empirical arguments about the PS hypothesis have concentrated on the non-stationarity of real commodity prices, which take the form of a non-random trend, the stochastic trend, or the structural jumps in the trend.

The original empirical surveys of Prebisch and the United Nations (1949) reinforced the theory. The evidence collected during the 1950s, 1960s, and 1970s, which has indicated continual upgrading in the quality of available commodity and manufacturing price indexes and more complex econometric techniques have been mingled. John Spraos (1980), Grilli and Yang (1988), Cuddington and Urzúa (1999), and D. Sapsford (1995) have investigated, made their analyses of the deteriorating trend from the indexes of international agencies, and provided conclusions, albeit, mostly depended on the PS hypothesis.

Spraos (1980) critique of the P-S hypothesis

At the start of his analysis, Spraos (1980) made an intriguing contention about the Prebisch-Singer hypothesis: that economist Prebisch (1950) lacked statistics (or there were gaps in the index) that forced him to depend on the index of a particular country, Britain. The prices of traded commodities did not elaborate on the origin of the products. His first contention was to retract later and support the theory of the existence of such trends with exaggerated statistics from Prebisch.

Spraos (1980) argues that Prebisch (1950 as cited in Spraos) only depended on the statistical data of the United Kingdom, and from this, he cut two overlapping indexes to cover the periods 1876 to 1880 andin to 1947, showing data improvement for Britain. The Spraos (1980) evidence states that since Britain, a major product manufacturer at that time was showing “secular improvement” the trend reflected a worldwide NBTT decline. There are critics of the hypothesis because of the gaps in the series. Prebisch argued that his data came from the UN (1949), which proved that his data was not t original (Spraos 1980).

She praos (1980) enumerates four major arguments against Prebisch’s (1950) hypothesis:

  1. They could not translate the NBTT data for the United Kingdom since the data from the industrialized world; could not be considered representative of the terms of trade of primary commodities (Spraos 1980);
  2. Developed countries also produced and exported primary products for industrialized countries, not only those coming from developing countries (Meier & Baldwin 1957; Meier 1958; Van Meerbehavior69; Frank 1976 cited in Spraos, 1980).
  3. They could neither attribute the rise in the United Kingdom’s NBTT to the reduction in transport expenses nor to the decline in the prices of primary products. The traders valued the exports based on the prices quoted for delivery in London, Liverpool (Viner 1953; Baldwin 1955; Ellsworth 1956; Meier & Baldwin 1957; Meier 1958, 1963 as cited in Spraos, 1980).
  4. The traders exported newly manufactured products and upgraded the existing ones, though the manufacturers did not state the specifications in the price index of manufacturers. Consequently, it provided an upward bias that vaguely created the impression that NBTT of primary products was declining (Viner 1953; Baldwin 1955, 1966; Ellsworth 1956; Meier & Baldwin 1957 as cited in Spraos, 1980).

Spraos (1980) criticizes the data by claiming that while the deteriorating trend is visible, it is not as conspicuous as suggested by Prebisch’s (1950) series. He further contends that the evidence contrary to the PS hypothesis is evident on the 1870 to 1938 data, but the declining trend is more doubtful when the period is extended forward. Moreover, index numbers formulated many years back have “conceptual problem errors of measurement” (Spraos 1980, p. 109). The question is whether the available series can plausibly represent the questionable NBTT or can clarify the plausible conclusions derived from those representations.

Spraos (1980) provides tests of the data considered the regression trends by supporting the assumptions acquired through visual analysis of the time series. The analysis did not explain the long-term movement of the terms of trade (given that it could produce high R2s), nor to acquire ‘efficient predictors’, nor ‘to seek the best fit on time’ (Spraos 1980, p. 109). He made semi-log-linear regression to show a measure of trend, where the coefficient of t provides the ‘average rate of change of the regression per unit time given implicitly in the data and the symbol of coefficient tests the hypothesis of deterioration’ (Spraos 1980, p. 109).

Spraos (1980) investigated Britain’s representative NBTT for industrialized countries. Some reliable author-economists, like Martin and Thackery (1948 as cited in Spraos) and Kindleberger (1956 as cited in Spraos), also investigated the combined NBTT of industrialized countries and reported that there was no significant trend in their NBTT up to World War II. During the same period, there was no significant trend reported for the US NBTT and industrial Europe concerning imported primary products and exported manufacturers.

Spraos (1980) produces a table, representing the League of Nations series, which has a compilation of world trade data. The purpose of this table and analysis is to examine whether Prebisch (1950 as cited in Spraos, 1980) gravely misled himself and the economic world by not using accurate evidence for his hypothesis. By using log regressions of the series on t, the Prebisch series provides ‘an annual rate of change of the relative price of primary products’ which is –0.9 percent, and the League series is –0.6 percent. The analysis presents evidence of an exaggeration not only in Prebisch’s data but also in League’s series.

According to Spraos (1980, p. 253), Lewis (1952) improved League’s data by adding ‘the prices of imports and exports of manufactures of the United States and in other ways.’ The League’s series shows robustness, and the UN Secretariat added a conceptual homogeneity. Based on the data collected by Spraos (1980), Britain’s NBTT as the basis for the relative price of primary products concerning manufacturers in worldwide trade ‘was not misleading as to the direction though it gave an exaggerated impression of the magnitude of deterioration’ (Spraos 1980, p. 113). Britain, which behavior the leading world trade country at that time, had a large and improved NBTT (Spraos 1980).

Spraos (1980) has made thorough analyses of the deteriorating trend for the 70 years up to World War II and concluded that indeed there was evidence of the trend in the relative price of primary products. However, there are reservations on the quality of the evidence, although he concluded after making key considerations in questioning the inference of the deteriorating trend. He, however, discovered that Prebisch (1950) exaggerated the rate of deterioration – ‘at worse by a factor of more than three (Spraos 1980, p.126).

The Grilli and Yang (1988) index

Grilli and Yang (1988) focus on the long-term run of prices of primary commodities and their index has become one of the most sought-after sources on the subject. Their main concern is to analyze the price movements but not to provide economic explanations for this phenomenon. They start with their initial finding that having high-quality price indexes is necessary when testing the PS hypothesis. The authors provide data on the prices of nonfuel commodities. They compare the statistical properties between the movements in those commodities and the manufactured products. After this examination, the author-economists further investigate the potential consequence of development on the commodity prices.

Grilli and Yang (1988) modified the United Nations Index in what became known as MUVUN (Manufactured Unit Values, United Nations) based on the Economist Index (EI) and the Lewis Index (WALIl), then used this to analyze 24 nonfuel product prices. They used the 1977-1979 data as weights. The new index – the GYCPI – tells of the movements in different periods of primary commodities. The index filled the two gaps (1914 to 1920 and 1939 to 1947) in the price index by way of their adopted strategy of ‘interpolation,’ utilizing product values of the United States and the United Kingdom during the period, as indicators.

Grilli and Yang further re-estimated the time trend model using their new commodity index and found a statistically significant long-term deterioration in the NBTT. Their econometric analysis focused on the likelihood of first-order serial correlation and structural breaks. The analysis also noted the ‘examination of the residuals of the semi-log time regressions, as well as a priori knowledge of the exogenous factors that may have caused a structural break in the price series. It was an indication from the possibility of breaks at three points in time: 1921, 1932 and 1945’ (Grilli & Yang 1988, p. 10).

At this time, we can conclude that the modified index (MUV) is more reliable as Grilli and Yang filled the gaps to provide complete data for the 1900-1986 deteriorating trend of the NBTT of primary commodities and manufactured goods in developing and developed countries. The researchers also developed another index of domestic prices of products made in the United States (example: energy, timber, and metal), as they wanted to avoid the overlapping of goods in the indexes. The index is used to provide a concept of the connection between ‘prices and unit values of exports’ along the period considering the logic of the results derived through interpolation (Grilli & Yang 1988, p. 5).

The two indexes now provide a relative trend growth for the period (1900 to 1986), equivalent to 2.49 percent annually for the MUV (this is shown in figure 1). The USMPI has exhibited 2.48 percent a year. However, the authors argue that the MUV is relatively erratic compared to the USMPI. The MUV has a ‘percentage deviation from trend’ of 6.2 percent for the 1900 to 1986 period, while the USMPI only got 5.1 percent. (Grilli & Yang 1988, p. 5).

Comparison of the indexes of manufactured goods prices for MUV and USMPI, 1900 to 1986
Figure 2 Comparison of the indexes of manufactured goods prices for MUV and USMPI, 1900 to 1986.

The two indexes were taken to calculate two collections of relative prices of primary commodities (nonfuel). The first set of commodity prices calculates the beginnings of the purchasing power of the domestically- traded primary commodities;

Cuddington and Urzúa’s (1999) critique

Cuddington and Urzúa (1999) examined the NBTT downward trend and the Grilli and Yang (1988) index. The authors applied the “time-series methods” and discussed the cyclical characteristics of commodity prices using the Beveridge and Nelson (1981) technique. The interest in the cyclical movements in commodity prices is founded on the principle that in policymaking the scope, length, and form of the cycles are as important as the current long-term trend.

In examining the NBTT downward trend, Cuddington and Urzua (1999) used the Grilli-Yang commodity price index (GYCPI) which, as mentioned earlier, explored 24 non-fuel commodities as weights and built a new index due to the gaps in the series, as discussed earlier. The GYCPI provided a picture of the significant drop in the NBTT and the other commodity prices examined by their index. Thirlwall and Bergevin (1985) also noticed the drop after analyzing the United Nations data from 1954 to 1982. Cuddington and Urzúa (199) found the advantage and relevance of Grilli and Yang’s (1988) index as all the other studies ignored the relevance of the serial correlation shown in the price movements.

Moreover, Cuddington and Urzúa (1999) found that the GYCPI was the most logical to use because the other used indexes – the World Bank, UNCTAD, and IMF – lacked data as they applied only the periods after the war. Similarly, they had applied the Economist Index (EI). The GYCPI used an annual index of manufactured goods unit values, also called MUV-GY. This series matches with the index of unit values computed by the equivalent United Nations manufactured goods unit values, or MUV-UN, which had gaps. Grilli and Yang filled the gaps through interpolation.

The NBTT sequence taken through deflation of GYCPI by MUV-GY produces the index of real commodity prices used by Cuddington and Urzúa (1999). The series is denoted y(t) in Cuddington and Urzúa’s analysis and is considered as good as the others, but they noted that the MUV-GY does not have the power on possible changes in the quality of either manufactured goods or primary commodities. It is one of the problems noted in the literature, where we could not account for quality changes while determining the actual commodity prices. Cuddington and Urzúa (1999) have cited Grilli and Yang’s (1988) remarks on the possibility of an “upward bias” borne by manufactured goods prices as they integrate the advantages of technological development that might have improved the goods’ quality (Cuddington & Urzúa, 1999).

All the other studies, excluding Grilli and Yang’s (1988), failed to provide statistical details of the univariate illustrations of the price movements that represented the different years. In other words, all those suppositions had regression difficulties.

Cuddington and Urzúa (1989) considered the price movements as nonstationary. In their analysis of GYCPI, they rebuffed the doctrine of determinism and supported the stochastic trend model using the test methods of Dickey and Fuller (1979), along with the method of Perron (1988). Here, Cuddington and Urzúa (1999) concluded that there was no deterioration in the NBTT for the period from 1900 to 1983. When they focused on the statistical problems caused by non-stationary, they concluded that there was no significant secular deterioration in the relevant commodity prices. They supported the Grilli and Yang findings.

The findings showed that the significant deterioration in commodity prices vanished when the latter considered the TS specification and the large break in the data after 1920 (Cuddington & Urzúa 1989, p. 441). In their examination of the residuals from simple TS and DS models, they concluded that there was a gap in the Grilli-Yang index after 1920, where Grilli and Yang explained that the data breaks referred to ‘exogenous’ events.

The sharp drop in prices after World War II explains the adjustment in commodity supplies and demands following the war. They also quoted Friedman and Schwartz’s theory in the belt-tightening policies of the Federal Reserve in 1920. The literature provides statements that in real terms, commodity prices exhibit invisible or dropping movements, but there are indications of long-term drops. Deaton (1999) argues that although the trend is erratic, we also see a variance.

Cuddington and Urzúa (1999) concluded that the Prebisch-Singer hypothesis applies with changes: that primary commodity prices relative to manufactures had a sharp drop after 1920. It is a one-time drop, and there is no continuing downward trend in the prices of primary goods. According to Cuddington & Urzúa (1999, p. 441), it is inappropriate to describe the movement of real primary commodity prices since the turn of the century as one of ‘secular deterioration.’ But, indeed, Cuddington and Urzúa recognized that there is a downward trend which supports the other studies, although the disagreement is on the period the trend stopped.

One worrying feature of the Cuddington-Urzúa (1999) paper is their ad hoc methodology for separating structural breaks. It was Cuddington and Urzúa’s examination of the residuals from simple TS and DS specifications that led them to the result that there was a gap in the Grilli-Yang index after 1920. This “data snooping” might not be good because it leads us to choose a point with a high Chow-test value.

Cuddington and Urzúa (1989, p. 429-430) admitted that ‘in light of its critical importance in our findings below, this sharp drop in prices cries out for some explanation… Presumably, it reflects the adjustment in commodity supplies and demands following the end of the First World War.’ They went on to paraphrase Friedman and Schwartz’s discussion of the belated tightening in Federal Reserve policy in 1920. Unfortunately, the conclusion regarding the trend in commodity prices seems to hinge critically on whatever the break is considered in the time series analysis.

The DS and TS models

The TS model suggests that ‘all price fluctuations around the deterministic trend line (which has a zero slope here) should be viewed as cyclical; the deterministic trend reflects changes in the permanent component of prices’ (Cuddington & Urzúa 1999, p. 438). The DS model provides a ‘decomposition of price innovations into permanent and cyclical components, with the former being stochastic rather than deterministic.’

D. Sapsford (1985) evidence

Sapsford (1985) criticized Spraos’s (1980) analysis and conclusion of the PS hypothesis regarding the NBTT declining trend. Sapsford’s analysis also supports the PS hypothesis, but at the same time, he criticizes Sprao’s methodology due to the statistical problem. Sapsford’s (1995) methodology drew a simple trend model from the methodology used by Spraos:

Equation (1) NBTTt = a + rt + ut (t = I, …, n)

By using regression methods, Sapsford (1985, p. 782) provides the ‘long-run trend of growth in the NBTT.’ He is subject to Spraos’s support of the PS hypothesis for the pre-World War II period which was acquired by using fitting model (I) using the ordinary least-squares (OLS) to two of the series, the United Nations series, which included the 1950 to 1970 period, and the World Bank index (post-1950 period). Sapsford criticized Spraos’s method of trend analysis and estimation, considering it to be only applicable on the premise that the primary constraints of the NBTT’s growth direction remain unchanged during the analysis of the index (Sapsford 1985, p. 782).

Sapsford (1985) found evidence of discontinuous changes in Spraos’s commodity price data. He observed the structural instability and allowed ‘intercept and slope dummies in 1950,’ allowing him to conclude that there was evidence supporting the PS hypothesis for the pre-and post-World War II periods.

In his study of Spraos’s (1980) analysis, Sapsford took note of the equations provided in a table stating the Cochrane-Orcutt (C-O) counterparts and Spraos’s regressions. The OLS or the C-O equations made to provide the structural instability in the growth during the pre and postwar periods results from the data provided by Spraos, that created 1900 to 1970 negative and significant growth rate which supports the PS hypothesis. (Sapsford 1985, p. 783)

Table 1 shows Spraos’s regression analysis. Absolute t values are presented in the figures in parentheses; the single asterisk represents the ‘coefficient which is significantly different from zero at the 5 percent level.’ NBTT represents the UN series, which is updated to 1980 with data taken from the United Nations Statistical Yearbook (1981 as cited in Sapsford, 1985). The results of the Spraos series support the P-S hypothesis: there is an upward trend before the war and a downward trend after the war, which shows a similar trend during the 1900 period up to the outbreak of the Second World War.

However, Sapsford (1985) notices that the UN results provide a different trend. The equation does not show significant alteration in the intercept term but an upward trend after the war. The upward movement also shows that it cannot change the negative trend. The equation further shows that ‘the restriction that the trend growth rate in the UN series and the coefficient of D8 sums to zero in (I.12) is rejected at the 1% level on the usual t test’ (Sapsford 1985, p. 786), which creates evidence to support the PS hypothesis. It further provides a negative trend for both the pre-and post-war periods.

In the final analysis on Spraos’s series, Sapsford (1985) concludes that there is ‘structural instability problems’ in Spraos’s analysis when he provided a re-estimation of Spraos’s equations from the data provided which showed that there was a ‘lack of flow for the period 1900-70′ (Sapsford 1985, p. 787). Although Sapsford recognizes his limitations in his analysis compared to the work of Spraos, he concludes that ‘Spraos’s earlier findings were misleading’ (Sapsford 1985, p. 787).

Spraos’s regression analysis of the long-run trend in NBTT.
Table 1. Spraos’s regression analysis of the long-run trend in NBTT.

Data

Grilli and Yang (1988) explored the 24 non-fuel price indexes and the modified index because they wanted to provide a complete index that would examine not only the post-World War II period but also the periods before the war. The World Bank index started with the 1948 period and beyond while the United Nations index had gaps.

Since it is unfeasible to create a new price index of manufacturers that date back from 1900, they used a modified form of the MUVUN (Manufactured Unit Values, United Nations), which they constructed by interpolation to satisfy the continuity, taking both import and export unit value of manufactured goods of the United States and the United Kingdom as indicators. The authors achieved the interpolation by taking average values of the sub-indexes and by using the estimated equation to generalize the values of the MUV index. For the period from 1915 to 1920, the researchers succeeded in conducting interpolation by first-order regression of the MUV index with the import and export unit values of manufactures indexes of the United States and the United Kingdom.

Some variable weights reflected the relative significance of the various types of manufacturers in international trade. The GYCPI is often referred to and discussed by economic researchers. Additionally, Grilli and Yang (1988) built sub-indexes for agricultural food commodities (GYCPIF), non-food agricultural commodities (GYCPINF), and metals (GYCPIM). The value of the weights relies on each product’s standard price for the period. (Bleaney & Greenaway 2001; Kimet et al. 2003).

Important sources used by Pfanffenzeller, Newbold, and Rayner (2007) provide more information on the commodity price data, such as the World Bank Development Prospects Group’s CPI, the IMF price tables, and the OECD database. Most of these data can be retrieved through the respective organizations’ websites. Grilli and Yang (1988) have to combine one or two indexes because of the incompleteness of the data. However, it creates some problems, and a challenge to the researchers, because finding the perfect match in the data is difficult to do. Figure 2 displays the GYCPI.

The GYCPI 1900-2010.
Figure 3. The GYCPI 1900-2010.

Stephan Pfaffenzeller, Paul Newbold, and Anthony Rayner (2007) maintain that the composite index defined by Grilli and Yang (1988) is computed as a weighted average of the commodity prices, which is:

Equation

Where n=24, ar is ‘the appropriate commodity weight,’ and Pit is the price of commodity i in period t , catalogued to 1977-1979 mean. Cuddington and Wei (1992) suggested that it might be better to use a geometric aggregation to define the index that is expressed as:

Equation

Cuddington and Wei (1992) discussed the specific features of this alternative index in detail. ‘Manufacturing unit value index,’ referred to in Cuddington and Wei (1992), is taken to reinforce the GYCPI, now termed MUV-G5 indexes. It is an index for the G5 countries and World Bank but regarded as an unsuitable measure for imports of developing countries. The MUV is used to measure manufactured products, which is referred to in the MUV 15 index, or the 15 countries.

The indexes are the equivalent to the total of each country’s exports, and the parts are calculated using the SITC tool for exports. In the manufacturing sector, Grilli and Yang (1988) used the OECD Producer Price Index (PPI).

The respective countries’ relative weights have different percentages, as shown in the table below.

Table 1. The 15 countries with relative weights comprising the MUV 15

Country Relative weight(%)
Brazil2.95
Canada0.93
China11.79
France5.87
Germany13.29
India1.77
Italy6.07
Japan16.70
Mexico0.93
South Africa0.75
Spain2.30
Thailand2.51
The United Kingdom3.50
The United States19.68

The MUV5, representing France, Germany, Japan, the United States, and the United Kingdom, has another set of data. The World Bank maintains that the time horizon and frequency used in predicting the MUV (15) are the same as the data used in the commodity price prediction.

The MUV 1900 – 2010.
Figure 4. The MUV 1900 – 2010.

The MUV receives regular updates so that the data coincide with the Global Economic Prospects and other predictions. The World Bank, through its agency the Development Prospects Group, also provides updates. Grilli and Yang (1988) regularly use the 1977-1979 averaging value with 1990 as the base year.

Nonfuel commodity prices have lagged even during the early 1900s compared to those of manufacturers in the U.S. and other manufactured products coming from industrial countries. These are considered or noted, in the BYCPI and USMPI series as these showed a negative exponential trend of 0.57 percent a year over the 1900 to 1986 period. On the other hand, the GYCPI and MUV series exhibit a trend decline of 0.59 percent a year over the same period. The figure below demonstrates the decline.

The aggregate trends in the relative prices of primary commodities, 1900-86.
Table 2 shows the aggregate trends in the relative prices of primary commodities, 1900-86.

The GYCPI shows that the purchasing power of nonfuel primary commodities about the manufacturers dropped since 1900 at an annual rate of 0.63 percent to 0.67 percent. In including the fuel prices in the index with the use of the GYCPI, the decline fell to 0.52 percent annually. The prices of primary commodities and nonfuel commodities dropped on trend since the period 1900 to 1986.

They used ‘the possibility of a change in slope’ through regression used by Suits, Mason, and Chan (1978 as cited in Grilli and Yang, 1988, p. 10) to check the stability of the estimated time coefficients of Grilli and Yang’s (1988) indexes (GYCPI/MUV and GYCPI”’/MUV regressions). Grilli and Yang found ‘no clear break’ that occurred since the 1900 period. World War I made a mark on the cyclical instability in commodity prices which showed in the first forty years covered by the Grilli and Yang series.

Grilli and Yang (1988) also computed the price trends of the three primary commodities categories relative to those of manufacturers, such as food (GYCPIF), non-food agricultural raw material prices (GYCPINF), and metal (GYCIPIM). They found that the decline in the relative prices was not uniform. The long-term decline showed in the metal and non-food agricultural product prices. In other words, not all producers of nonfuel primary commodities did feel the relative prices fall ‘in the purchasing power of a given volume of their products over the past eighty-six years’ (Grilli & Yang 1988, p. 11).

The commodity price indexes that include Grilli and Yang (1988), the MUV, GYCPIM are incorporated in a long table shown in Appendix 1.

Methodology

The research focuses on the long-term behavior of commodity prices. To achieve this aim, series analysis models were used.

Unit Root Test

Two characteristics of ‘economic time series are known as ‘trending behavior and non-stationarity (Grilli & Yang 1988). These two also influence financial time series.

Any inference based on an unspecified model may be misleading unless the model. A necessary first is to determine the order of integration of the data, which may be achieved using a unit root test.it also llrthealsolsoll athe lso assure appropriateness of the model chosen to make more accurate predictions. Amonwhichrtargetiwhichettheewh chthe the is called augmented Dickey-Fuller (ADF) test, popular to be used in more complicated models for time series. Assume autoregressive model about time series yt as below:

Equation

where α is the drift, β is the coefficient associated with the linear deterministic trend and κ is the lag order.

The augmeDickey-Fullerubbased basedbased onistatisticsialsorelto with the significance of negative coefficient γ. The null hypothesis states that the data in question has a unit root which may as:

H0: gamma = 0 in equation 4

The stability of the estimated time coefficients of Grilli and Yang’s (1988) indexes (GYCPI/MUV and GYCPI”’/MUV regressions), the expression of an alternative hypothesis is:

H1: gamma <1 in equation 4

The ADF test is calculated using:

Equation

In (equation 5) gamma hat and SE (gamma hat are obtained from OLS estimation of equation 4.

is smaller than the critical value related at a given confidence level, and null hypothesis gamma = 0 will be rejected, implying that there is no evidence of a unit root in the data of interest. In addition, before calculating DF statistics, lag order κ sshould also be determined. If the lag order k is incorrectly specified for equation (4) then inference about the presence of a unit root based on tests constructed as (equation 5) may be invalid.

We compute the delta coefficients in (equation 4). One approach is, to begin with, a high order fork and to test down until the kth lag coefficient is significant. However, the most serious disadvantage is that higher lag order seems to be preferable by this method without considering the appropriateness and complexity of the model.

There is another feasible approach for measuring the relative quality of the model with certain lag order by trading off complexity and goodness of the model, such as Akaike information criterion (AIC) or Bayesian information criterion (BIC). In this project, the Akaike information criterion (AIC) will be applied to estimate lag order κ, which can be shown in the following equation:

Equation

Where k is the lag order and L is maximized likelihoostatisticianisticaent that AIC offers a relative estimate of complexity increase by lag order k and information lost by likelihood L , assuming that AIC is more appropriate.

In addition, EViews has been chosen as the statistic software for this project. EViews can easily give the result whether the data has the unit root. If the data reject the null hypothesis, it means the data does not have a unit root. If EViews accept the null hypothesis, it indicates that the data is non-stationery. When the data does not have this property, we can also test its first-order stationarity. Once we have the result about the stationarity of the data, we can do the regression model. We will apply ARMA and ARIMA models for the nonstationary data.

ARMA model

ARMA is an acronym for the autoregressive moving average model, according to Peter (1952) to aid in mathematical analysis, particularly econometrics. Hannan and Deistler (1988) also gave their expertise, using the Box-Jenkins method. ARMA can be used to describe a stationary time series, and to predict future values, using a time series of two parts, ‘the autoregressive and the moving average’ (Grilli & Yang 1988). This is represented in the symbol AR(p), and calculated using the formula:

Equation

The formula has the following representations: mi=1…p as coefficients, o can be considered constant, while εt represents the random variable. Considering moving-average model, the one with order q , noted by MA(q), can be written as:

Equation

where εt, εt- 1 … are white noise error terms, ni, i=1 … q, are the corresponding coefficients of error terms and μ is drift part. RMA (p,q), has the following equation.

Equation

Equivalently, ARMA model can also be specified by lag operator L. By these simplifying notations; the alternative AR(p) model is given by (Equation 10) Equation and the alternative MA (q) model is given by (Equation 11) Equation

Thus, Box and Reinsel (1994) used a different method to estimate ARMA coefficients that allow ARMA to be similar expression as polynomial. Thus, the ARMA (p,q) model could be expressed in (Equation 12)

Equation

When suitable values of p and q are estimated, least, squares regression uses the ARMA models to estimate coefficients in ARMA. ARMA p and q must have appropriate data which can be taken from autocorrelatifunctiontan ionsons. AIC can be used to find p and was recommended by Brockwell & Davis (2009).

ARIMA

ARIMA is acronym for ‘autoregrethethegrated moving average,’ the considered an additional tool for ARMA. The difference between ththe ese two similar models is that ARdifferencessyed in some situations when data do not show stationary propertyreferredred an initial differencinis g method can be used to eliminate the nonstationarity, which is reered to as ARIMA (p, d, q) model.

p – Represents the autoregressive order; d for the integrateorderdrandd orr the ‘moving average order’ of ARIMA. ARIMA models come from the general ARMA model which is expressed in the following formula:

(Equation 13)

Equation

Where L indicates the lag operator, the mi are the autoregressive parameters of the model; the ni are the parameters appearing in the moving average part and the ε1 denote error terms. The term εt is considered a randolong-termependent thearconcluded‘normal distribution.’ Assume now that the polynomiala Equation has a unitary root of multiplicity a which means that it can be rewritten as:

(Equation 14)

Equation

Doing the change of parameters with p=p-a will lead an ARIMA (p, d, q) model to such a f mula:

(Equation 15)

Equation

Results

The stationarity of the data

The stationarity of GYCPI/MUV for the period 1900 – 1986

The result for examining the stationarity of GYCPI/MUV is illustrated in table 2. From this table, EViews gives the probability 0.1125 and t-statistic value for Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic with -3.095835 which is larger than the 10% level. It indicates that there is no significant evidence against the null hypothesis of a unit root. This evidence suggests that there is a unit root in the level of the GYCPI/MUV series.

Given the apparent unit root in the level of GYCPI/MUV, we will look at its first difference, denoted as D(GYCPI/MUV). Table 3 shows the result of checking the stationarity of D(GYCPI/MUV). This evidence suggests that there is no unit root in the first difference of the GYCPI/MUV series. It is consistent with the view that this series is I(1).

The stationarity of GYCPICW/MUV

The GYCPI/MUV and GYCPICW/MUV 1900-2010.
Figure 5. The GYCPI/MUV and GYCPICW/MUV 1900-2010.

The result in examining the stationarity of GYCPICW/MUV is illustrated in table 6. From this table, we can see EViews gives the probability 0.2128 and t-statistic value for Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic with -2.766571 which is larger than the 10% level. There is no evidence against the null of a unit root in GYCPICW/MUV. The evidence is consistent with the view that the data are non-stationary.

Again, given the apparent unit root in the level of GYCPICW/MUV, we will look at its first difference, denoted as D(GYCPICW/MUV). Table 7 shows the result of checking the stationarity of D(GYCPICW/MUV). The evidence suggests that there is no unit root in the first difference of GYCPICW/MUV. It is consistent with the view that this series is I(1).

The stationarity of GYCPIM/MUV

The GYCPIM and GYCPIMCW/MUV 1900-2010.
Figure 6 The GYCPIM and GYCPIMCW/MUV 1900-2010.

The result for examining the stationarity of GYCPIM/MUV is shown in. From this table, we can see EViews gives the probability 0.4088 and t-statistic value for Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic with -2.339955 which is larger than the 10% level. There is no evidence against the null of a unit root in GYCPIM/MUV. The evidence is consistent with the view that the data are non-stationary.

Given the evidence of a unit root in the level of GYCPIM/MUV, we will look at its first difference, denoted as D(GYCPIM/MUV). Table 11 shows the result of checking the stationarity of D(GYCPIM/MUV). The evidence suggests that there is no unit root in the first difference of GYCPIM/MUV. It is consistent with the view that this series is I(1).

The stationarity of GYCPIMCW/MUV

The result for examining the stationarity of GYCPIMCW/MUV is shown in table 14. EViews gives the probability 0.1549 and t-statistic value for Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic with – 2.937905 which is larger than the 10% level. There is no evidence against the null of a unit root in GYCPIMCW/MUV. The evidence is consistent with the view that the data are non-stationary.

The evidence suggests that there is a unit root in the level of GYCPIMCW/MUV. If there is no evidence of a unit root in the first difference of the series, this would be consistent with the view that this series is I(1). Table 15 shows the result of checking the stationarity of D(GYCPIMCW/MUV). The evidence suggests that there is no unit root in the first difference of GYCPIMCW/MUV. It is consistent with the view that this series is I(1).

The stationarity of GYCPINF/MUV

The result for examining the stationarity of GYCPINF/MUV is shown in. From this table, EViews gives the probability 0.0370 and t-statistic value for Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic with -3.571039 which is less than 5% level. There is no evidence of a unit root in the level of GYCPINF/MUV.

The stationarity of GYCPINFCW/MUV

The result for examining the stationarity of GYCPINFCW/MUV is shown in. From this table, we can see EViews gives the probability 0.0214 and t-statistic value for Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic with -3.777520 which is less than 5% level. There is no evidence of a unit root in the level of GYCPINFCW/MUV.

GYCPINF and GYCPINFCW/MUV 1900-2010.
Figure 7 GYCPINF and GYCPINFCW/MUV 1900-2010.

The stationarity of GYCPIF/MUV

The result for examining the stationarity of GYCPIF/MUV is shown in. From this table, we can see EViews gives the probability 0.0151 and t-statistic value for Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic with -3.901358 wh, ich is less than 5% level. There is no evidence of a unit root in the level of GYCPIF/MUV.

The GYCPIF and GYCPIFCW/MUV 1900-2010.
Figure 8 The GYCPIF and GYCPIFCW/MUV 1900-2010.

The stationarity of GYCPIFCW/MUV

The result for examining the stationarity of GYCPIFCW/MUV is shown in table 27. The result of 0.1211 can be taken from EViews and t-statistic value for Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic with -3.060341 which is a bit larger than the 10% level. There is no evidence against the null of a unit root in GYCPIFCW/MUV. The evidence is consistent with the view that the data are non-stationary.

Given the evidence of a unit root in the level of GYCPIFCW/MUVis, we have to look at its first difference, denoted as D(GYCPIFCW/MUV). Table 28 shows the result of checking stationarity of D(GYCPIFCW/MUV). The evidence suggests that there is no unit root in the first difference of GYCPIFCW/MUV. It is consistent with the view that this series is I(1).

It is accepted among the storage model theorists that agricultural prices should be stationary. With an i.i.d. supply and a deterministic demand function, the storage model seeks to show how commodity storage induces price auto-correlation. Under the Prebish-Singer hypothesis, there exists some literature that has focused on the stationarity of price. The primary reason this phenomenon happened was the low-income elasticity of commodity demand and the high prices caused by manufacturers’ market power.

The policy also has effects on the price stationarity. It should be emphasized that there is obvious randomness regarding the existence of trends in agricultural commodities. Moreover, trends do not seem to sustain for a very long time given the assumption of the existence of trends. Since it is unknown whether prices have trends, and whether price shocks are consistent, one reasonable solution at the level of producer and national may be extending commodity production, and this would probably diminish the risks connected with the existence of shocconcludedity.

The regression

To get the regression model for each index, we should check the values of all the parameters first. For those indexes with stationary property, ARMA will be used for regression, and those indexes without stationary property, and ARIMA will be implied. ARMA model needs two parameters p and q to be determined, and the ARIMA model needs three parameters p, d, and q to be determined. Some criteria can be chosen to determine the parameter values.

The Akaike information criterion (AIC) (Akaike, 1974) and Schwarz information criterion (SIC) (Schwarz, 1978) are two objective measurements to check the goodness of fitting for a model that takes those considerations into account. The order consists of a criterion is described to be the criterion is minimized at the true order with a probability that approaches agreement as to the sample size increases. The AIC procedure has however been criticized because of the lotermestance and trends in overfitting models. Shibata (1976) demonstrated this for the autoregressive model, Geweke and Meese (1981) for regression models, and Hannan (1982) applies the model.

The ARIMA model of GYCPI/MUV

The result of choosing parameters of ARIMA for GYCPI/MUV is shown in the table 4. The least AIC appears in ARIMA (1,1,1) with value 7.81. Table 5 gives the regression result for GYCPI/MUV. As we can see, the probabilities of C, AR(1) and MA(1) are all below 5%. This result means this ARIMA (1,1,1) fits GYCPI/MUV very well. Denotes GYCPI/MUV as ‘C,’ then we have the following regression formula:

(Equation 16)

Equation

The ARIMA model of GYCPICW/MUV

The result of choosing parameters of ARIMA for GYCPICW/MUV is shown in the table 8. The least AIC appears in ARIMA (1,2,2) with value 7.09. Table 9 gives the regression result for GYCPICW/MUV. As we can see, the probabilities of AR(1) and MA(2) are both below 5%. This result indicates that this ARIMA (1,2,2) model fitsGYCPICW/MUV well. Denotes GYCPICW/MUV as ‘CW,’ is then we have the following regression formula:

(Equation 17) ,

Equation

The ARIMA model of GYCPIM/MUV

The result of choosing parameters of ARIMA for GYCPIM/MUV is shown in table 12. The minimum AIC appears in ARIMA (0,2,3) with value 8.81. Table 13 gives the regression result for GYCPIM/MUV. As we can see, the probabilities of MA(1), MA(2) and MA(3) are all below the% concluded A(0,2,3) fits GYCPIM/MUV very well. Denotes GYCPIM/MUV as ‘CM,’ then we have the following regression formula:

(Equation 18)

Equation

The ARIMA model of GYCPIMCW/MUV

The result of choosing parameters of ARIMA for GYCPIMCW/MUV is shown in the table 16. The minimum AIC appears in ARIMA (1,2,2) with value 8.09. Table 17 gives the regression result for GYCPIMCW/MUV. As we can see, the probabilities of AR(1) and MA(2) are both above 5%. This result means the ARIMA (1,2,2) model does not fit GYCPIMCW/MUV very well. Denotes GYCPIMCW/MUV as ‘CMW,’ then we have the following regression rmula:

(Equation 19)

Equation

The ARMA model of GYCPINF/MUV

The result oa f choosing parameters of ARIMA for GYCPINF/MUV is shown in the table 19. The minimum Aappliespears in ARMA (2,2) with value 8.12. Table 20 gives the regression result for GYCPINF/MUV. As we can see, the probabilities of AR(1),AR(2), MA(1) and MA(2) are all below 5%. This result strongly means the ARMA (2,2) modelfitsGYCPINF/MUV very well. This result means this ARMA (2,2) fits GYCPINF/MUV very well. Denotes GYCPINF/MUV as ‘CN,’ then we have the following regression formula:

(Equation 20)

Equation

The ARMA model of GYCPINFCW/MUV

The result of choosing parameters of ARIMA for GYCPINFCW/MUV is shown in the table 22. The minimum AIC appears in ARMA (1,2) with value 7.43. Table 23 gives the regression result for GYCPINFCW/MUV. As we can see, the probabilities of AR(1), and MA(2) are all below 5%. This result tells us that the ARMA (1,2) model fits GYCPINFCW/MUV very well. Thithe s result means this ARMA (1,2) fits GYCPINFCW/MUV very well. Denotes GYCPINFCW/MUV as ‘CNW,’ then we have the following regression formula:

(Equation 21)

Equation

The ARMA model of GYCPIF/MUV

The result of choosing parameters of ARIMA for GYCPIF/MUV is shown in the table 25. The minimum AIC appears in ARMA (1,2) with value 8.24. Table 26 gives the regrusinglt for GYCPIF/MUV. As we can see, the probabilities of AR(1) and MA(2) are all below 5%. This result indicates that this ARMA (1,2) model fitsGYCPIF/Mpost-1950Denotes GYCPINF/MUVcriticizedthen we have the following regression formula:

(Equation 22) pre-and Equation

The ARIM model of GYCPIFCW/MUV

The result of choosing parameters of ARIMA for GYCPIFCW/MUV is shown in the table 29. The minimum AIC appears in ARIMA (0,2,3) wialue 7.45. Table 30 gives the regression result for GYCPIFCW/MUV. As we can see, the probabilities of MA(1), MA(2) and MA(3) are all below 5% that means this ARIMA (0,2,3) fits GYCPIFCW/MUV very well. Denotes GYCPIFCW/MUV as ‘CFW,’ then we have the following regression formula:

(Equation 23)

Equation

The Q-stat values suggest that these models are free from neglected serial correlation and therefore can be used to produce potentially valid forecasts for the various series.

The forecast of commodity price index

The result of the static forecast for every commodity price index is given in figures 1 to 8. From the result, it is easy to find that the forecast interval of geometric weights is lower than the forecast interval of arithmetic weights for each index. It means that using geometric weights will make the data easier to forecast. However, we found in the literature that the decline in the relative prices of primary commodities cannot be ascertained because of the lack of long-term factor productivity growth in developing countries, the source of agricultural and mining products. Productivity growth impacts real export prices (Grilli & Yang 1988, p. 35).

Conclusion

The research is based on examining the long-term trends of commodity price indexes. This study investigates the stationary property of each commodity price index. The period of the sample is from 1900 to 2011 and includes four kinds of commodity price indexes concerning two different weights algorithms. This study reviewed the theories and empirical studies of the various economists’ arguments on the long-term movements of commodity prices, especially on the declining trend of nonfuel commodity prices from 1900 to 2011.

In a bid to reach the main objective, many statistical methods were applied. First, the augmented Dickey-Fuller test was chosen to be a method to test the stationarity of the data. There are several reasons that ADF is our choice. One reason is that this test is used by Eviews which is the statistic software chosen in this project. Stationary testing uses arithmetic weights that can ‘bring’ more stationarity.

After unit root testing, EViews were again used to complete the estimation. For those indexes with stationary property, ARMA was used for regression, and those indexes without stationary property, ARIMA was implied. We used the Akaike information criterion to determine the lag lengths of the ARMA and ARIMA models.

Through the estimation of ARMA and ARIMA models, we managed to get several regression models for commodity price indexes. The Q-stat values suggest that these models can do forecast future values. The results presented in this thesis are important because we found that empirical evidence on the prices of exported and imported goods, particularly nonfuel primary commodity prices between developed and developing countries needs to be presented and strengthened. This was presented in the literature review and strengthened in the methodology. This study provided a glimpse of the economies of the past through prices of primary commodities and how economists relate prices with economic policies.

References

Akaike, H 1974, A new look at the statistical identification model IEEE: Trans. Auto Control, vol. 19, no. 1, pp. 716-723. Web.

Beveridge, S & Nelson, C 1981, A new approach to decomposition of economic time series into permanent and transitory components with particular attention to measurement of the ‘business cycle: Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 7, no. 1, pp. 151-174. Web.

Bloomberg, S Brock, E & Harris, E 1995, The commodity consumer prices connection: fact or fable, vol. 1, no. 3, pp. 21– 38. Web.

Box, G, Jenkins, G & Reinsel, G 1994, Time series analysis: forecasting and control, third edition, Prentice-Hall, New York, U.S.

Brockwell P & Davis, R. 2009, Time-series: theory and methods, 2nd edn, Springer, New York, USA.

Cashin, P & McDermott, C 2002, The long-run behavior of commodity prices: small trends and big variability: IMF Staff Papers, vol. 49, no. 2, pp. 175-199. Web.

Cuddington, J T 1990, Long-run trends in 26 primary commodity prices: a disaggregated look at the Prebisch-Singer hypothesis: Journal of Development Economics, vol. 1, no.1, pp. 3-18. Web.

Cuddington, J & Urzúa, C 1999, Trends and cycles in the net barter terms of trade: a new approach, vol. 99, no. 1, pp. 426-442. Web.

Deaton, 1999, Commodity prices and growth in Africa: Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 13, no. 1, pp. 23-40. Web.

Dickey, D Bell, W & Miller, R 1986, Unit roots in time series models: tests and implications, vol. 31, no. 1, pp. 12-26. Web.

Diebold, F & Kilian, L 1999, Unit root tests are useful for selecting forecasting models. NBER Working Paper no. 6928, vol. 1, no. 2, pp. 3-28. Web.

Garner, C 1995, How useful are leading indicators of inflation? Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City Economic Review (2nd Quarter), vol. 1, no. 1, pp. 5–18. Web.

Greene, W 1997 Econometric analysis, 3rd edn, Macmillan Publishing Company, USA.

Grilli, E & Yang, M 1988, Primary commodity prices, manufactured goods prices, and terms of trade of developing countries: what the long run shows: World Bank Economic Review, vol. 2, no. 1, pp. 1-48. Web.

Gweke, J & Meese, R 1981, Estimating regression models of finite but unknown order: International Economic Review, vol. 22, no. 1, pp. 55-70. Web.

Hannan, E 1970, Multiple time series, John Wiley and Sons, New York.

Hannan, E 1982, Testing for autocorrelation and Akaike’s criterion,’ in Gani, W & Hannan, E (eds): Essays in statistical science, Applied Probability Trust, Shefield, pp. 403-412.

Hannan, E & Deistler, M 1988, Statistical theory of linear systems, John Wiley and Sons, Inc., New York.

Harvey, A 1985, Trends and cycles in macroeconomic times series: Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, vol. 3, no. 1, pp. 216-227. Web.

Harvey, D Kellard, N Madsen, J & Wohar, M 2010, The Prebisch-Singer hypothesis: four centuries of evidence: Review of Economics and Statistics, vol. 92, no. 2, pp. 367-377. Web.

Lutz, M 1999, Commodity terms of trade and individual countries’ net barter terms of trade: is there an empirical relationship? Journal of International Development, vol. 11, pp. 859-870. Web.

Nelson, C. R & Kang, H 1984, Pitfalls in the use of time as an explanatory variable in regression: Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, vol. 2, pp. 73-82. Web.

Perron, P 1988, Trend and random walks in macroeconomic time series, further evidence from a new approach: Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, vol. 12, pp. 297-332. Web.

Pfaffenzeller, S Newbold, P & Rayner, A n.d., A Short note on updating the Grilli and Yang commodity price index: The World Bank Economic Review, vol. 21, No. 1, pp. 151–163. Web.

Plosser, C & Schwert, G 1978, Money, income, and sunspots: measuring economic relationships and the effects of differencing: Journal of Monetary Economics, vol. 4, no. 1, pp. 637-660. Web.

Prebisch, R 1950, The economic development of Latin America and its principal problems, United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America, Michigan.

Said, S & Dickey, D 1984 Testing for unit roots in autoregressive moving-average Models with unknown order, Biometrika, New York, USA.

Sapsford, D 1985, The Statistical debate on the net barter terms of trade between primary commodities and manufactures: a comment and some additional evidence: Economic Journal, vol. 95, no. 1, pp. 781-788. Web.

Schwarz, G 1978, Estimating the dimension of a model: Ann Statist., vol., no. l6, pp. 461-464. Web.

Shibata, R 1976, Selection of the order of an autoregressive model by Akaike’s information criterion: Biometrika, vol. 63, pp. 117-126. Web.

Singer, H. (1950). ‘The distribution of giants between investing and borrowing Countries’, American Economic Review, vol. 1, pp. 473-485. Web.

Spraos, J (1980). ‘The statistical debate on the net barter terms of trade between primary commodities and manufactures’, Economic Journal, vol. 1, pp. 107-128. Web.

Thirlwall, A P & Bergevin, J (1985). ‘Trends, cycles, and asymmetries in the terms of trade of primary commodities from developed and less developed countries, World Development, vol. 13, pp. 805-817. Web.

United Nations. (1949). Relative prices of exports and imports of under-developed countries, Lake Success, New York.

Urzúa, C. M 1989, Trends, and cycles in the net barter terms of trade, vol. 1, no. 1, pp. 426-442. Web.

Von Hagen, J 1989, The relative commodity prices and co-integration, vol. 1, pp. 497-503. Web.

Whittle, P 1951, Hypothesis testing in time series analysis, Almquist and Wicksell, New York.

Whittle, P 1963, Prediction and Regulation, English Universities Press, London.

Whittle, P. 1983, Prediction and regulation by linear least-square methods, University of Minnesota Press, Minnesota.

Appendix 1

The following are data and tables taken from the Grilli and Yang (1988) indexes and shown with their 1977-1999 averages. The acronyms have corresponding data information, as explained in the literature; in particular, the CYCPIM represents the metals index; the CYCPINP for the non-food products; and the CYCPIF for the agricultural food products.

===================== Table 1a. (Yr. 1900- 1916) =====================

YearMUVGYCPIGYCPIMGYCPINFGYCPIFGYCPICWGYCPIMCWGYCPINFCWGYCPIFCW
190014.60719.30927.77821.3115.58712.86620.06411.04912.014
190113.85818.23627.52219.29214.71612.00818.48510.36611.232
190213.48318.14525.51819.26815.20911.87817.26810.43311.22
190313.48319.00626.66822.8614.63412.17318.67211.42410.938
190413.85820.58627.52624.4516.44413.0718.83511.33712.459
190513.85821.62129.1526.22616.92413.62420.89811.69312.793
190614.60721.6131.72627.54715.42213.75923.90412.51912.057
190715.35622.75736.69925.96716.67214.08925.43512.4212.386
190814.23220.42724.24522.29118.27613.52617.79711.50113.41
190914.23221.55420.82228.97318.14313.78716.62312.83713.443
191014.23222.6321.02632.92418.08814.22416.78113.50413.834
191114.23221.90919.92328.12219.49814.77316.73112.86315.195
191214.60722.6423.17628.16619.73915.61119.73113.33815.642
191314.60720.46123.13425.4417.14914.59219.15113.48813.893
191413.85820.2119.29122.23919.50914.64216.27213.23114.878
191514.23224.46831.32124.38822.29217.72323.2615.83917.158
191617.60331.93350.32730.89726.49722.23734.08521.67119.614

===================== Table 1b. (Yr. 1917- 1940) =====================

YearMUVGYCPIGYCPIMGYCPINFGYCPIFGYCPICWGYCPIMCWGYCPINFCWGYCPIFCW
191720.97439.39645.27140.25737.07427.25534.10930.25624.07
191825.46842.02835.12142.84143.86130.73130.41935.78728.595
191926.96639.20830.85343.29239.90231.1525.86134.47731.464
192028.83941.95129.68439.64147.05229.63124.67232.65229.968
192124.34521.35620.21921.60521.60216.90416.43318.89616.145
192221.72321.9119.91924.77121.14717.17617.09719.40116.195
192321.72326.40724.58729.98925.23419.61520.31622.48118.128
192421.72326.52125.06628.36526.08620.31920.53420.84319.996
192522.09729.38126.31536.77826.63722.11222.07524.00521.243
192620.97425.75825.96228.69124.2520.11721.82220.04519.628
192719.8525.14324.02826.82324.67719.75920.12419.90419.57
192819.8524.42323.58525.39324.21719.9720.01519.8919.995
192919.10123.26625.2122.33223.09819.11421.14318.16118.975
193018.72718.27721.65516.94917.83815.08516.72715.76914.272
193115.35613.6118.47912.30812.67511.00212.89410.1310.888
193212.73410.79716.8838.9589.7348.78710.7347.7228.779
193314.23212.59118.38812.35710.83310.24313.29210.2919.393
193416.85415.76318.59116.42714.52212.82514.81313.62311.88
193516.47917.29418.38316.22917.46513.65415.17813.2713.382
193616.47918.41818.67718.34818.36914.54315.29914.63214.263
193716.85421.36120.93120.36621.98817.12718.06416.8416.976
193817.60316.55218.47416.19816.10513.48115.15314.17312.663
193916.10516.01919.18817.49914.26713.06216.02714.74911.513
194017.60317.23718.93220.54715.06314.12216.02317.89712.058

===================== Table 1c. (Yr. 1941- 1964) =====================

YearMUVGYCPIGYCPIMGYCPINFGYCPIFGYCPICWGYCPIMCWGYCPINFCWGYCPIFCW
194118.72720.09318.45224.84418.28817.03216.13122.10715.237
194221.72323.07318.03927.71622.41919.59316.10724.76118.594
194324.34524.28318.13229.09423.90520.60516.3526.56819.583
194427.71525.24318.13230.78624.81621.27816.3528.62720.01
194528.46425.83218.23230.11226.18621.50416.58427.14920.843
194628.83931.23219.48532.68834.31425.50118.36129.7226.293
194734.83140.38924.70937.34946.95233.42623.14633.63537.532
194835.58138.72227.9840.93441.10733.16826.12237.34933.79
194933.33335.84526.47935.72738.9330.33124.90130.59632.192
195030.33739.26327.76745.0640.1332.65326.03636.67433.175
195135.95548.09332.46658.70247.92939.64730.55748.52639.031
195236.70440.50831.82545.98340.62335.28729.97341.72634.241
195335.20637.89732.21440.83938.28933.47729.98536.94833.041
195434.45738.56533.06639.79739.73834.21630.54335.71434.752
195534.83138.23338.26742.53736.10734.21334.69538.52832.116
195636.3339.89540.97741.51738.74736.66436.93138.42135.741
195736.70440.10835.37642.37240.52536.58532.54139.05936.79
195836.3336.23132.54638.64736.23533.52530.06936.05733.498
195936.3337.11335.37940.66735.92634.70732.67537.07234.256
196037.07937.32736.78141.79935.30535.04533.76339.22233.548
196137.45336.46635.24240.42434.91734.05332.73838.15332.604
196237.45336.48634.73439.89335.37733.71932.6537.1132.495
196337.45341.41934.74739.08444.72336.69333.15836.07538.236
196438.20241.04637.6239.78242.77438.25136.34937.17439.441

===================== Table 1d. (Yr. 1965- 1988) =====================

YearMUVGYCPIGYCPIMGYCPINFGYCPIFGYCPICWGYCPIMCWGYCPINFCWGYCPIFCW
196538.95138.11940.49939.9936.42935.75839.09538.32633.569
196639.737.93540.56837.44537.32535.29738.95335.3734.154
196739.736.84641.50933.81336.8334.42539.87432.21433.921
196839.32637.43143.91434.6236.71835.21142.21333.23334.167
196940.44939.76147.71237.45938.32237.80545.32436.10936.468
197042.69742.20153.536.43841.38140.19449.76335.59639.833
197145.31842.32450.29337.63842.05140.03446.98237.03839.504
197248.68946.62549.61343.82347.03743.60746.89542.53843.119
197358.80169.47255.7269.05474.12363.95153.11866.96766.38
197471.161102.4179.81374.718123.3384.80377.41573.7393.6
197579.02685.15676.0965.80797.59873.49474.45265.0277.757
197678.65283.1181.40878.94685.70780.10579.96477.7681.336
197786.51793.12587.75290.68196.06492.19387.31690.25194.823
197898.87693.62791.14994.17394.15993.42690.94394.14193.89
1979114.61113.25121.1115.15109.78112.388120.204114.786108.827
1980125.47138.83144.72126.49142.99128.818138.845125.138127.547
1981119.1117.94124.21108.87120.38113.227123.156108.409112.583
1982115.7396.784110.5496.72792.36494.597108.24195.84589.976
1983110.49102.78118.37103.1597.566100.094114.464102.29994.814
1984108.61103.54112.81105.2999.686100.297108.995104.25695.783
1985109.5991.268105.5990.4987.02288.034100.87989.37983.608
1986130.388.358105.3486.02684.01384.12297.01484.28480.253
1987142.995.215108.047118.20379.69490.567103.931117.0776.295
1988153.3116.574155.777124.23100.101109.537142.006121.92795.511

===================== Table 1e. (Yr. 1989- 2011) =====================

YearMUVGYCPIGYCPIMGYCPINFGYCPIFGYCPICWGYCPIMCWGYCPINFCWGYCPIFCW
1989152.925118.705151.529129.335102.826108.972140.342127.15893.027
1990166.647113.918135.879139.30994.255102.306124.454135.07883.691
1991165.558103.689111.752130.24987.94594.312102.724125.23779.734
1992171.841101.897111.151122.76788.5891.564102.345117.18778.179
1993170.12399.06895.373115.68392.04889.7388.804111.07281.015
1994170.123114.839115.39132.639105.858109.502107.21130.351101.148
1995171.841128.768138.508154.315112.983121.763126.433151.673107.908
1996168.075123.471118.752146.121113.797115.837112.093142.603105.637
1997168.634120.882122.247142.559109.72115.79112.656138.579106.891
1998167.617106.33399.364125.90798.909101.7594.276119.95996.139
1999165.44593.31197.679115.64980.8587.32292.105108.42577.115
2000161.94592.753107.338112.76678.13684.93999.488107.26171.907
2001157.17988.6895.077106.4177.84279.42588.17100.66968.292
2002155.21292.11490.655112.58582.46383.80384.233107.98773.805
2003166.85398.87999.672127.84884.29790.45693.482125.15876.22
2004178.361112.819141.579133.1193.477103.338135.162129.68384.674
2005178.361121.482167.96132.433101.025111.463154.674128.02393.612
2006181.215153.017282.602144.449115.317131.615242.454138.424105.344
2007189.732177.004311.703180.202131.828154.51282.438170.109121.205
2008202.444194.575290.844173.006174.086174.555271.662165.591155.269
2009191.039163.481219.018150.592151.882151.037203.246143.264140.833
2010195.844204.535306.068196.923175.441189.339280.874190.159166.297
2011211.988254.44367.429234.367227.799235.046334.232225.341214.155

Table 2 GYCPI/MUV.

Null Hypothesis: GYCPI has a unit root
Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend
Lag Length: 0 (Automatic – based on SIC, maxlag=12)
t-StatisticProb.*
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic-3.0958350.1125
Test critical values:1% level-4.042819
5% level-3.450807
10% level-3.150766
*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.
Dependent Variable: D(GYCPI)
Method: Least Squares
Sample (adjusted): 1901 2011
VariableCoefficientStd. Errort-StatisticProb.
GYCPI(-1)-0.1956000.063182-3.0958350.0025
C27.521299.5434792.8837790.0047
@TREND(1900)-0.1224980.057506-2.1301670.0354
R-squared0.083957Mean dependent var-0.109589
Adjusted R-squared0.066993S.D. dependent var12.12960
S.E. of regression11.71626Akaike info criterion7.786488
Sum squared resid14825.25Schwarz criterion7.859718
Log-likelihood-429.1501Hannan-Quinn criteria.7.816195
F-statistic4.949177Durbin-Watson stat1.747009
Prob(F-statistic)0.008779

Table 3 The Difference of GYCPI/MUV.

Null Hypothesis: D(GYCPI) has a unit root
Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend
Lag Length: 0 (Automatic – based on SIC, maxlag=12)
t-StatisticProb.*
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic-10.051530.0000
Test critical values:1% level-4.043609
5% level-3.451184
10% level-3.150986
*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.
Dependent Variable: D(GYCPI,2)
Method: Least Squares
Sample (adjusted): 1902 2011
VariableCoefficientStd. Errort-StatisticProb.
D(GYCPI(-1))-0.9782270.097321-10.051530.0000
C-1.2002612.391399-0.5019080.6168
@TREND(1900)0.0194800.0368900.5280520.5986
R-squared0.485765Mean dependent var0.147147
Adjusted R-squared0.476153S.D. dependent var16.96536
S.E. of regression12.27907Akaike info criterion7.880563
Sum squared resid16132.98Schwarz criterion7.954212
Log-likelihood-430.4310Hannan-Quinn criteria.7.910436
F-statistic50.53796Durbin-Watson stat1.978445
Prob(F-statistic)0.000000

Table 4 AICs for different p and q of D (GYCPI/MUV).

P000111223
Q123012010
AIC7.867.827.837.867.817.827.857.827.88

Table 5. ARIMA model for GYCPI/MUV.

Dependent Variable: D(GY_CPI_MUV)
Sample (adjusted): 1902 2011
Included observations: 110 after adjustments
Convergence achieved after 9 iterations
MA Backcast: 1901
VariableCoefficientStd. Errort-StatisticProb.
AR(1)-0.6898520.333427-2.0689750.0409
MA(1)0.7851830.2860852.7445770.0071
R-squared0.017220Mean dependent var-0.105147
Adjusted R-squared0.008121S.D. dependent var12.18503
S.E. of regression12.13545Akaike info criterion7.808153
Sum squared resid15905.07Schwarz criterion7.897253
Log-likelihood-429.6484Hannan-Quinn criteria.7.868069
Durbin-Watson stat2.093991
Inverted AR Roots-.69
Inverted MA Roots-.79

Table 6 GYCPICW/MUV.

Null Hypothesis: GYCPICW has a unit root
Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend
Lag Length: 0 (Automatic – based on SIC, maxlag=12)
t-StatisticProb.*
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic-2.7665710.2128
Test critical values:1% level-4.042819
5% level-3.450807
10% level-3.150766
*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.
Dependent Variable: D(GYCPICW)
Method: Least Squares
Sample (adjusted): 1901 2011
VariableCoefficientStd. Errort-StatisticProb.
GYCPICW(-1)-0.1556810.056272-2.7665710.0067
C15.712086.0562262.5943690.0108
@TREND(1900)-0.0329820.029836-1.1054440.2714
R-squared0.067813Mean dependent var0.205369
Adjusted R-squared0.050550S.D. dependent var8.720614
S.E. of regression8.497340Akaike info criterion7.144039
Sum squared resid7798.117Schwarz criterion7.217269
Log-likelihood-393.4941Hannan-Quinn criteria.7.173746
F-statistic3.928300Durbin-Watson stat1.665835
Prob(F-statistic)0.022551

Table 7 The Difference of GYCPICW/MUV.

Null Hypothesis: D(GYCPICW) has a unit root
Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend
Lag Length: 1 (Automatic – based on SIC, maxlag=12)
t-StatisticProb.*
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic-8.7572820.0000
Test critical values:1% level-4.044415
5% level-3.451568
10% level-3.151211
*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.
Dependent Variable: D(GYCPICW,2)
Method: Least Squares
Sample (adjusted): 1903 2011
VariableCoefficientStd. Errort-StatisticProb.
D(GYCPICW(-1))-1.1570160.132120-8.7572820.0000
D(GYCPICW(-1),2)0.2582710.0971772.6577520.0091
C-0.4070221.704311-0.2388190.8117
@TREND(1900)0.0102690.0261810.3922280.6957
R-squared0.486009Mean dependent var0.116998
Adjusted R-squared0.471323S.D. dependent var11.82555
S.E. of regression8.598380Akaike info criterion7.177032
Sum squared resid7762.875Schwarz criterion7.275797
Log-likelihood-387.1482Hannan-Quinn criteria.7.217085
F-statistic33.09452Durbin-Watson stat1.979725

Table 8 AICs for different p and q of D (D(GYCPICW/MUV).

P000111223
Q123012010
AIC7.217.227.287.677.237.097.497.267.45

Table 9ARIMA model for GYCPICW/MUV.

Dependent Variable: D(D(GY_CPICW_MUV))
Method: Least Squares
Included observations: 109 after adjustments
Convergence achieved after 18 iterations
MA Backcast: 1901 1902
VariableCoefficientStd. Errort-StatisticProb.
AR(1)-0.9290160.036188-25.671840.0000
MA(2)-0.9566550.019783-48.356770.0000
R-squared0.446327Mean dependent var0.116998
Adjusted R-squared0.441152S.D. dependent var11.82555
S.E. of regression8.840324Akaike info criterion7.094702
Sum squared resid8362.193Schwarz criterion7.164085
Log-likelihood-391.2013Hannan-Quinn criteria.7.234729
Durbin-Watson stat1.867566
Inverted AR Roots-.93
Inverted MA Roots.98-.98

Table 10 GYCPIM/MUV.

Null Hypothesis: GYCPIM has a unit root
Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend
Lag Length: 2 (Automatic – based on SIC, maxlag=12)
t-StatisticProb.*
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic-2.3399550.4088
Test critical values:1% level-4.044415
5% level-3.451568
10% level-3.151211
*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.
Dependent Variable: D(GYCPIM)
Method: Least Squares
Sample (adjusted): 1903 2011
VariableCoefficientStd. Errort-StatisticProb.
GYCPIM(-1)-0.1415220.060481-2.3399550.0212
C18.2999910.321471.7730020.0792
@TREND(1900)-0.0465800.075574-0.6163550.5390
R-squared0.199355Mean dependent var-0.146194
Adjusted R-squared0.168561S.D. dependent var20.50837
S.E. of regression18.70021Akaike info criterion8.739732
Sum squared resid36368.57Schwarz criterion8.863189
Log-likelihood-471.3154Hannan-Quinn criteria.8.789799
F-statistic6.473820Durbin-Watson stat1.952630
Prob(F-statistic)0.000108

Table 11 The Difference of GYCPIM/MUV.

Null Hypothesis: D(GYCPIM) has a unit root
Exogenous: Constant
Lag Length: 1 (Automatic – based on SIC, maxlag=12)
t-StatisticProb.*
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic-9.2986310.0000
Test critical values:1% level-3.491345
5% level-2.888157
10% level-2.581041
*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.
Dependent Variable: D(GYCPIM,2)
Method: Least Squares
Sample (adjusted): 1903 2011
VariableCoefficientStd. Errort-StatisticProb.
D(GYCPIM(-1))-1.1043600.118766-9.2986310.0000
D(GYCPIM(-1),2)0.3471670.0930643.7304040.0003
C-0.2924691.833485-0.1595160.8736
R-squared0.475260Mean dependent var0.242049
S.D. dependent var26.16133S.E. of regression19.12894
Akaike info criterion8.767419Sum squared resid38787.14
Schwarz criterion8.841493Log-likelihood-474.8243
Hannan-Quinn criteria.8.797459F-statistic48.00235
Durbin-Watson stat1.992121

Table 12 AICs for different p and q of D (D (GYCPIM/MUV)).

P000111223
Q123012010
AIC8.908.848.819.338.878.909.368.878.91

Table 13 ARIMA model for GYCPIM/MUV.

Dependent Variable: D(D(GY_CPIM_MUV))
Method: Least Squares
Included observations: 110 after adjustments
Convergence achieved after 22 iterations
MA Backcast: 1899 1901
VariableCoefficientStd. Errort-StatisticProb.
MA(1)-0.8338480.093320-8.9353360.0000
MA(2)-0.4185960.119828-3.4933080.0007
MA(3)0.2706340.0946142.8604000.0051
R-squared0.448898Mean dependent var0.078299
Adjusted R-squared0.438597S.D. dependent var26.09762
S.E. of regression19.55412Akaike info criterion8.811143
Sum squared resid40912.90Schwarz criterion8.884792
Log-likelihood-481.6129Hannan-Quinn criteria.8.841016
Durbin-Watson stat1.868662
Inverted MA Roots.98.46-.60

Table 14 GYCPIMCW/MUV.

Null Hypothesis: GYCPIMCW has a unit root
Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend
Lag Length: 1 (Automatic – based on SIC, maxlag=12)
t-StatisticProb.*
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic-2.9379050.1549
Test critical values:1% level-4.043609
5% level-3.451184
10% level-3.150986
*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.
Dependent Variable: D(GYCPIMCW)
Method: Least Squares
Sample (adjusted): 1902 2011
VariableCoefficientStd. Errort-StatisticProb.
GYCPIMCW(-1)-0.1640490.055839-2.9379050.0041
D(GYCPIMCW(-1))0.2565170.0985132.6038910.0105
C17.599597.2046862.4427980.0162
@TREND(1900)-0.0262620.046530-0.5644020.5737
S.E. of regression13.40749Akaike info criterion8.065191
Sum squared resid19054.66Schwarz criterion8.163390
Log-likelihood-439.5855Hannan-Quinn criteria.8.105021
Durbin-Watson stat1.908410

Table 15 The Difference of GYCPIMCW/MUV.

Null Hypothesis: D(GYCPIMCW) has a unit root
Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend
Lag Length: 1 (Automatic – based on SIC, maxlag=12)
t-StatisticProb.*
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic-8.4327200.0000
Test critical values:1% level-4.044415
5% level-3.451568
10% level-3.151211
*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.
Dependent Variable: D(GYCPIMCW,2)
Method: Least Squares
Sample (adjusted): 1903 2011
VariableCoefficientStd. Errort-StatisticProb.
D(GYCPIMCW(-1))-1.0619990.125938-8.4327200.0000
D(GYCPIMCW(-1),2)0.2540000.0975872.6027910.0106
C-2.3780292.702874-0.8798150.3810
@TREND(1900)0.0449070.0415591.0805640.2824
S.E. of regression13.57534Akaike info criterion8.090394
Sum squared resid19350.44Schwarz criterion8.189159
Log-likelihood-436.9265Hannan-Quinn criteria.8.130447
Durbin-Watson stat2.036146

Table 16 AICs for different p and q of D (D(GYCPIMCW/MUV)).

P000111223
Q123012010
AIC8.158.138.108.578.128.098.468.108.36

Table 17 ARIMA model for GYCPIMCW/MUV.

Dependent Variable: D(D(GY_CPIMCW_MUV))
Sample (adjusted): 1903 2011
Included observations: 109 after adjustments
Convergence achieved after 13 iterations
MA Backcast: 1901 1902
VariableCoefficientStd. Errort-StatisticProb.
AR(1)-0.9259730.037566-24.649090.0000
MA(2)-0.9534140.020263-47.052920.0000
R-squared0.404810Mean dependent var0.179492
Adjusted R-squared0.399248S.D. dependent var18.13454
S.E. of regression14.05576Akaike info criterion8.092120
Sum squared resid21139.39Schwarz criterion8.191502
Log-likelihood-441.7455Hannan-Quinn criteria.8.162146
Durbin-Watson stat1.726598
Inverted AR Roots-.93
Inverted MA Roots.98-.98

Table 18 GYCPINF/MUV.

Null Hypothesis: GYCPINF has a unit root
Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend
Lag Length: 0 (Automatic – based on SIC, maxlag=12)
t-StatisticProb.*
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic-3.5710390.0370
Test critical values:1% level-4.042819
5% level-3.450807
10% level-3.150766
*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.
Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Equation
Method: Least Squares
Sample (adjusted): 1901 2011
VariableCoefficientStd. Errort-StatisticProb.
GYCPINF(-1)-0.2277490.063777-3.5710390.0005
C36.2469610.822423.3492480.0011
@TREND(1900)-0.1899760.071506-2.6567770.0091
R-squared0.106412Mean dependent var-0.318308
Adjusted R-squared0.089864S.D. dependent var15.20003
S.E. of regression14.50099Akaike info criterion8.212965
Sum squared resid22710.09Schwarz criterion8.286196
Log-likelihood-452.8196Hannan-Quinn criteria.8.242673
F-statistic6.430537Durbin-Watson stat1.778004
Prob(F-statistic)0.002298

Table 19. AICs for different p and q of GYCPINF/MUV.

P1111222334
Q1234123121
AIC8.278.228.248.168.278.128.218.138.138.15

Table 20 ARMA model for GYCPINF/MUV.

Dependent Variable: GY_CPINF_MUV
Method: Least Squares
Sample (adjusted): 1902 2011
Included observations: 110 after adjustments
Convergence achieved after 25 iterations
VariableCoefficientStd. Errort-StatisticProb.
AR(1)1.5710760.10750114.614480.0000
AR(2)-0.5747390.106609-5.3911150.0000
MA(1)-0.6686590.123406-5.4183640.0000
MA(2)-0.3040410.120056-2.5324900.0128
R-squared0.848573Mean dependent var113.2865
Adjusted R-squared0.844287S.D. dependent var36.03817
S.E. of regression14.22083Akaike info criterion8.122979
Sum squared resid21436.59Schwarz criterion8.221178
Log-likelihood-446.0638Hannan-Quinn criteria.8.222809
Durbin-Watson stat2.033904
Inverted AR Roots.99.58
Inverted MA Roots.98-.31

Table 21 GYCPINFCW/MUV.

Null Hypothesis: GYCPINFCW has a unit root
Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend
Lag Length: 0 (Automatic – based on SIC, maxlag=12)
t-StatisticProb.*
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic-3.7775200.0214
Test critical values:1% level-4.042819
5% level-3.450807
10% level-3.150766
*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.
Dependent Variable: D(GYCPINF_CW)
Method: Least Squares
Sample (adjusted): 1901 2011
VariableCoefficientStd. Errort-StatisticProb.
GYCPINF_CW(-1)-0.2314380.061267-3.7775200.0003
C23.750986.4810543.6646780.0004
@TREND(1900)-0.0395120.031016-1.2739380.2054
R-squared0.116715Mean dependent var0.276190
Adjusted R-squared0.100358S.D. dependent var10.42580
S.E. of regression9.888812Akaike info criterion7.447340
Sum squared resid10561.17Schwarz criterion7.520571
Log-likelihood-410.3274Hannan-Quinn criteria.7.477048
F-statistic7.135422Durbin-Watson stat1.745378
Prob(F-statistic)0.001229

Table 22 AICs for different p and q of GYCPINFCW/MUV.

P1111222334
Q1234123121
AIC7.437.437.457.467.437.457.467.467.487.48

Table 23 ARMA model for GYCPINFCW/MUV.

Dependent Variable: GY_CPINFCW_MUV
Sample (adjusted): 1901 2011
Included observations: 111 after adjustments
Convergence achieved after 8 iterations
MA Backcast: 1899 1900
VariableCoefficientStd. Errort-StatisticProb.
AR(1)0.9993490.006609151.21780.0000
MA(2)-0.3613530.091232-3.9607900.0001
R-squared0.624115Mean dependent var92.14567
Adjusted R-squared0.620666S.D. dependent var16.27652
S.E. of regression10.02472Akaike info criterion7.425838
Sum squared resid10953.95Schwarz criterion7.514659
Log-likelihood-412.3540Hannan-Quinn criteria.7.485643
Durbin-Watson stat1.985436
Inverted AR Roots1.00
Inverted MA Roots.60-.60
Dependent Variable: GY_CPINFCW_MUV
Method: Least Squares
Date: 11/24/13 Time: 22:04
Sample (adjusted): 1901 2011
Included observations: 111 after adjustments
Convergence achieved after 8 iterations
MA Backcast: 1899 1900
VariableCoefficientStd. Errort-StatisticProb.
AR(1)0.9993490.006609151.21780.0000
MA(2)-0.3613530.091232-3.9607900.0001
R-squared0.624115Mean dependent var92.14567
Adjusted R-squared0.620666S.D. dependent var16.27652
S.E. of regression10.02472Akaike info criterion7.465838
Sum squared resid10953.95Schwarz criterion7.514659
Log-likelihood-412.3540Hannan-Quinn criteria.7.485643
Durbin-Watson stat1.985436
Inverted AR Roots1.00
Inverted MA Roots.60-.60
Dependent Variable: GY_CPINFCW_MUV
Method: Least Squares
Date: 11/24/13 Time: 22:04
Sample (adjusted): 1901 2011
Included observations: 111 after adjustments
Convergence achieved after 8 iterations
MA Backcast: 1899 1900
VariableCoefficientStd. Errort-StatisticProb.
AR(1)0.9993490.006609151.21780.0000
MA(2)-0.3613530.091232-3.9607900.0001
R-squared0.624115Mean dependent var92.14567
Adjusted R-squared0.620666S.D. dependent var16.27652
S.E. of regression10.02472Akaike info criterion7.465838
Sum squared resid10953.95Schwarz criterion7.514659
Log-likelihood-412.3540Hannan-Quinn criteria.7.485643
Durbin-Watson stat1.985436
Inverted AR Roots1.00
Inverted MA Roots.60-.60

Table 24 GYCPIF/MUV.

Null Hypothesis: GYCPIF has a unit root
Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend
Lag Length: 0 (Automatic – based on SIC, maxlag=12)
t-StatisticProb.*
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic-3.9013580.0151
Test critical values:1% level-4.042819
5% level-3.450807
10% level-3.150766
*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.
Dependent Variable: D(GYCPIF)
Method: Least Squares
Sample (adjusted): 1901 2011
VariableCoefficientStd. Errort-StatisticProb.
GYCPIF(-1)-0.2567800.065818-3.9013580.0002
C34.204649.2827673.6847460.0004
@TREND(1900)-0.1519510.059011-2.5749540.0114
S.E. of regression14.42287Akaike info criterion8.202162
Sum squared resid22466.07Schwarz criterion8.275393
Log-likelihood-452.2200Hannan-Quinn criteria.8.231870
Durbin-Watson stat1.886512

Table 25 AICs for different p and q of GYCPIF/MUV.

P1111222334
Q1234123121
AIC8.268.238.268.278.268.278.278.288.268.30

Table 26 ARMA model for GYCPIF/MUV.

Dependent Variable: GY_CPIF_MUV
Sample (adjusted): 1901 2011
Included observations: 111 after adjustments
Convergence achieved after 7 iterations
MA Backcast: 1899 1900
VariableCoefficientStd. Errort-StatisticProb.
AR(1)0.9938520.009760101.82590.0000
MA(2)-0.2894250.093547-3.0939100.0025
R-squared0.738724Mean dependent var100.0482
Adjusted R-squared0.736327S.D. dependent var28.85984
S.E. of regression14.81926Akaike info criterion8.227586
Sum squared resid23937.54Schwarz criterion8.296407
Log-likelihood-455.7410Hannan-Quinn criteria.8.267391
Durbin-Watson stat2.184502
Inverted AR Roots.99
Inverted MA Roots.54-.54

Table 27 GYCPIFCW/MUV.

Null Hypothesis: GYCPIFCW has a unit root
Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend
Lag Length: 0 (Automatic – based on SIC, maxlag=12)
t-StatisticProb.*
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic-3.0603410.1211
Test critical values:1% level-4.042819
5% level-3.450807
10% level-3.150766
*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.
Dependent Variable: D(GYCPIFCW)
Method: Least Squares
Sample (adjusted): 1901 2011
VariableCoefficientStd. Errort-StatisticProb.
GYCPIFCW(-1)-0.1716700.056095-3.0603410.0028
C17.156965.9883892.8650370.0050
@TREND(1900)-0.0458810.033934-1.3520410.1792
R-squared0.080300Mean dependent var0.169135
Adjusted R-squared0.063268S.D. dependent var10.16203
S.E. of regression9.835307Akaike info criterion7.436489
Sum squared resid10447.19Schwarz criterion7.509720
Log-likelihood-409.7252Hannan-Quinn criteria.7.466197
F-statistic4.714792Durbin-Watson stat1.775727
Prob(F-statistic)0.010887

Table 28 The Difference of GYCPIFCW/MUV.

Null Hypothesis: D(GYCPIFCW) has a unit root
Exogenous: Constant, Linear Trend
Lag Length: 1 (Automatic – based on SIC, maxlag=12)
t-StatisticProb.*
Augmented Dickey-Fuller test statistic-9.8384730.0000
Test critical values:1% level-4.044415
5% level-3.451568
10% level-3.151211
*MacKinnon (1996) one-sided p-values.
Dependent Variable: D(GYCPIFCW,2)
Method: Least Squares
Sample (adjusted): 1903 2011
Included observations: 109 after adjustments
VariableCoefficientStd. Errort-StatisticProb.
D(GYCPIFCW(-1))-1.2993840.132072-9.8384730.0000
D(GYCPIFCW(-1),2)0.3253130.0939953.4609460.0008
C-0.2120661.951645-0.1086600.9137
@TREND(1900)0.0061240.0299780.2042720.8385
S.E. of regression9.845976Akaike info criterion7.448010
Sum squared resid10179.04Schwarz criterion7.546775
Log-likelihood-401.9165Hannan-Quinn criteria.7.488063
Durbin-Watson stat1.942876

Table 29 AICs for different p and q of D (D(GYCPIFCW/MUV)).

P000111223
Q123012010
AIC7.517.537.458.057.547.507.777.467.70

Table 30 ARIMA model for GYCPIFCW/MUV.

Dependent Variable: D(D(GY_CPIFCW_MUV))
Method: Least Squares
Included observations: 110 after adjustments
Convergence achieved after 28 iterations
MA Backcast: 1899 1901
VariableCoefficientStd. Errort-StatisticProb.
MA(1)-0.9411090.093079-10.110870.0000
MA(2)-0.3514370.125074-2.8098380.0059
MA(3)0.3114490.0935763.3283050.0012
R-squared0.523177Mean dependent var0.157335
Adjusted R-squared0.514264S.D. dependent var14.18832
S.E. of regression9.888511Akaike info criterion7.447518
Sum squared resid10462.74Schwarz criterion7.521168
Log-likelihood-406.6135Hannan-Quinn criteria.7.477391
Durbin-Watson stat1.973607
Inverted MA Roots.97.55-.58

Figures 1 – 9 (Forecasts)

Forecast of GYCPI/MUV.
Figure 9 Forecast of GYCPI/MUV.
Forecast of GYCPICW/MUV.
Figure 10 Forecast of GYCPICW/MUV.
Forecast of GYCPIM/MUV.
Figure 11 Forecast of GYCPIM/MUV.
Forecast of GYCPIMCW/MUV.
Figure 12 Forecast of GYCPIMCW/MUV.
Forecast of GYCPINF/MUV.
Figure 13 Forecast of GYCPINF/MUV.
Forecast of GYCPINFCW/MUV.
Figure 14 Forecast of GYCPINFCW/MUV.
Forecast of GYCPIF/MUV.
Figure 15 Forecast of GYCPIF/MUV.
Forecast of GYCPIFCW/MUV.
Figure 16 Forecast of GYCPIFCW/MUV.
More related papers Related Essay Examples
Cite This paper
You're welcome to use this sample in your assignment. Be sure to cite it correctly

Reference

IvyPanda. (2022, April 9). The Long-Term Trends of Commodity Prices From 1900 to 2011. https://ivypanda.com/essays/the-long-term-trends-of-commodity-prices-from-1900-to-2011/

Work Cited

"The Long-Term Trends of Commodity Prices From 1900 to 2011." IvyPanda, 9 Apr. 2022, ivypanda.com/essays/the-long-term-trends-of-commodity-prices-from-1900-to-2011/.

References

IvyPanda. (2022) 'The Long-Term Trends of Commodity Prices From 1900 to 2011'. 9 April.

References

IvyPanda. 2022. "The Long-Term Trends of Commodity Prices From 1900 to 2011." April 9, 2022. https://ivypanda.com/essays/the-long-term-trends-of-commodity-prices-from-1900-to-2011/.

1. IvyPanda. "The Long-Term Trends of Commodity Prices From 1900 to 2011." April 9, 2022. https://ivypanda.com/essays/the-long-term-trends-of-commodity-prices-from-1900-to-2011/.


Bibliography


IvyPanda. "The Long-Term Trends of Commodity Prices From 1900 to 2011." April 9, 2022. https://ivypanda.com/essays/the-long-term-trends-of-commodity-prices-from-1900-to-2011/.

If, for any reason, you believe that this content should not be published on our website, please request its removal.
Updated:
This academic paper example has been carefully picked, checked and refined by our editorial team.
No AI was involved: only quilified experts contributed.
You are free to use it for the following purposes:
  • To find inspiration for your paper and overcome writer’s block
  • As a source of information (ensure proper referencing)
  • As a template for you assignment
Privacy Settings

IvyPanda uses cookies and similar technologies to enhance your experience, enabling functionalities such as:

  • Basic site functions
  • Ensuring secure, safe transactions
  • Secure account login
  • Remembering account, browser, and regional preferences
  • Remembering privacy and security settings
  • Analyzing site traffic and usage
  • Personalized search, content, and recommendations
  • Displaying relevant, targeted ads on and off IvyPanda

Please refer to IvyPanda's Cookies Policy and Privacy Policy for detailed information.

Required Cookies & Technologies
Always active

Certain technologies we use are essential for critical functions such as security and site integrity, account authentication, security and privacy preferences, internal site usage and maintenance data, and ensuring the site operates correctly for browsing and transactions.

Site Customization

Cookies and similar technologies are used to enhance your experience by:

  • Remembering general and regional preferences
  • Personalizing content, search, recommendations, and offers

Some functions, such as personalized recommendations, account preferences, or localization, may not work correctly without these technologies. For more details, please refer to IvyPanda's Cookies Policy.

Personalized Advertising

To enable personalized advertising (such as interest-based ads), we may share your data with our marketing and advertising partners using cookies and other technologies. These partners may have their own information collected about you. Turning off the personalized advertising setting won't stop you from seeing IvyPanda ads, but it may make the ads you see less relevant or more repetitive.

Personalized advertising may be considered a "sale" or "sharing" of the information under California and other state privacy laws, and you may have the right to opt out. Turning off personalized advertising allows you to exercise your right to opt out. Learn more in IvyPanda's Cookies Policy and Privacy Policy.

1 / 1