Competition and Entrepreneurship by Kirzner Review Report

Exclusively available on Available only on IvyPanda® Written by Human No AI

Description

In this book the author tries to develop an alternative to the conventional price theory. In doping so, he elucidates the problems with the conventional model and hoe the new model has helped to eliminate those issues. The author brings forth the question of an entrepreneur who acts as an agent in competition and shows how a perfect competition situation is led to become imperfect.

Kirzner tries to portray the different theories of prices and develop a new model of the same to eliminate the problems in the orthodox theory. Price theory in conventional microeconomics tries to explain relationships among observed market phenomena. The two alternative approaches of market theory that we come across in microeconomics are the orthodox neoclassical theory, developed mainly by Marshall, Robinson, Chamberlin and Walras and the Austrian market process theory that is proposed by Kirzner in the book “Competition and Entrepreneurship”.

The book aims to the following:

  1. questions the usefulness and the adequacy of the equilibrium analysis, including Robinson-Chamberlin theory of imperfect competition,
  2. offers a redefinition of the concept of monopoly and competition within the context of entrepreneurial activity,
  3. revamps the theoretical concept of advertising and product differentiation in light of the model he developed,
  4. Develops a new standard of economic welfare based on condition of knowledge rather than on the orthodox model of allocation of social resources standards and action.

The methodology adopted by Kirzner is a descriptive analysis of the prevalent theories and finding the issues involved in them. He does not make use of mathematics to analyze his model. He basically objects to the methodology of (Robinsonian) equilibrium analysis in which competition and imperfect competition are defined as situations. According to these theories, in a competitive market, buyers and sellers of homogeneous products are many and possessed of perfect knowledge of demand and cost functions. In such a model of perfect availability of information, Kirzner argues that “each individual knows with certainty what to expect, his plans can be completely explained interms of economizing, of optimal allocation, and of maximizing…” (p. 37). Thus the choice solution is implicit in a set of givens.

Production is the conversion of resources (inputs, factors, producer goods) into products (outputs, consumer goods). In a market with production, individuals can be grouped into resource owners, producers and consumers. Producers are entrepreneurs who buy resources from resource owners and sell them (in the form of a product) to consumers. Even if a producer owns one of the resources himself, he must ‘buy’ that resource from himself in the form of opportunity cost (what he could sell it for in the market). Production is arbitrage (entrepreneurship), the exploitation of price differences.

Production is inherently entrepreneurial and competitive, and cannot be monopolized. The situation of a single seller then must be analyzed taking into account whether the position is the result of offering the best opportunities to the market or the result of monopolized resource ownership. Monopolized resource ownership can be the result of competitive entrepreneurial activity.

Entrepreneurship requires no resources to be initially owned, and “pure” entrepreneurship (a mental tool) is exercised only in the absence of resource ownership.

Orthodox theory interprets human behavior as economizing (maximizing, allocative, “Robbinsian”). Individuals apply given means to given ends, and the best course of action is implied in these data. Changes in the means and ends are exogenous.

Market process theory interprets human behavior as human action, a wider view which includes the perception of means and ends. The orthodox individual is a mere calculator. “Mises” homo agens, on the other hand, is endowed not only with the propensity to pursue goals efficiently, once ends and means are clearly identified, but also with the drive and alertness needed to identify which ends to strive for and which means are available.” (p. 34).

The entrepreneurial element of every human action is “alertness to possibly newly worthwhile goals and to possibly newly available resources.” (p. 35) With perfect knowledge, the entrepreneurial element would be unnecessary, but in the real world, knowledge is imperfect.

Economic analysis can be simplified by separating decisions into entrepreneurial and economizing elements. “Consumers” and “resource owners” economize, and “entrepreneurs” display alertness (in real life, of course, an individual will fall into all the categories).

“Producers” are both entrepreneurs and economizers at different stages of production. If the producer contributes an input (for example, managerial skills), he is economizing. In deciding which inputs to hire and which outputs to produce, he is an entrepreneur. As entrepreneur the producer decides what he believes to be cost and revenue functions; as economizer the producer uses those judgments to select a production process. The initial decision to purchase inputs is entrepreneurial; once the inputs are acquired the decision to actually produce (or to change the initial plan instead) is the decision of a resource owner.

Profits result from resource ownership or from entrepreneurship. Owners’ profit results from an exchange, and is the difference between the value of what is received and the value of what is given up. Entrepreneurial profit is the difference between the price paid and the price received; nothing is given up. Profit is usually the result of more than one decision, and so can be viewed as either owners’ or entrepreneurial depending on which decision is being analyzed.

Capitalists are resource owners. A production process that takes time requires capital, that is, resources advanced by owners who agree to receive payment (with interest) at a later date.

Orthodox theory concentrates on the “firm” as the decision-maker in production, and firm’s behavior maximizes profit. In market process theory, the firm is the result of a partially-completed entrepreneurial decision, being basically an entrepreneur who has already acquired some resources. ‘Profit-maximization’ is not used to interpret firms’ behavior. The producer as resource owner maximizes the value of his resources, but as entrepreneur is alert to new uses for his resources.

The corporation poses a problem for orthodox theory because ‘control’ (managers) is separated from ‘ownership’ (capitalists or stockholders), so that profit may not be maximized. In market process theory, there is no problem. If the managers receive only their wages, they are hired resources; if they in addition extract other (possibly non-monetary) benefits from their position, they are acting also as entrepreneurs; if instead, they steal benefits, then revenue will not cover costs and they will be fired.

Entrepreneurship is not merely the possession of knowledge of price differences; such knowledge can be hired, in which case the one who does the hiring is the entrepreneur. Hiring itself can be hired (a personnel manager), in which case the one who hires the hirer is the entrepreneur. The entrepreneur is the one with the ultimate knowledge, the one who does the ultimate hiring, the one who decides to bring all the inputs together to produce an output.

Entrepreneurship is the ability of individuals to learn from market participation. This alertness to opportunities sets the market process in action, generating changes in individual plans, eliminating price differentials.

The objective of orthodox theory is to determine market equilibrium, generating numerical values for prices and quantities at which transactions are made. Orthodox theory analyzes the effects of exogenous change and policies in terms of their effects on equilibrium. Equilibrium is the “one set of planned activities” that allows all planned transactions to be carried out. (Kirzner, p. 4).

The objective of market process theory is to “understand how the decisions of individual participants in the market interact to generate the market forces which compel changes in prices, in outputs and in methods of production and the allocation of resources.” (p. 6).

Market participants make decisions (plans), many of which anticipate other participants’ actions. With imperfect knowledge, at the end of a given period, many individuals will find that their plans could not be carried out (too optimistic) or were carried out but failed to take advantage of more beneficial opportunities (too pessimistic). Through market participation, individuals see others’ actual decisions (often in the form of prices); gaining knowledge that causes them to revise their plans. This market process occurs even without change in the “data” or underlying conditions of trade.

With perfect knowledge, individual plans will be made so that none fail (from being too optimistic or pessimistic). The market process ceases (no adjustments occur), and equilibrium exists.

Analysis

Kirzner’s criticism of neoclassical equilibrium feature is based on his assertion that mainstream always assumes perfect competition and perfect knowledge. The Marshallian supply and demand curve simply reflects self-interested sellers looking for higher prices in order to offer more quantities for sale, and self-interested buyers looking for lower prices in order to purchase more quantities. Market participants conduct this bargain hunting with as much as their own knowledge, but no insistence of perfect knowledge.

In orthodox theory, competition and monopoly are situations; the theory models various market structures in equilibrium, labeling them ‘competitive’ or ‘monopolistic.’ The model of perfect competition is “the situation in which every market participant does exactly what everyone else is doing, in which it is utterly pointless to try to achieve something in any way better than what is already being done by others, and in which, in fact, it is not necessary to keep one’s eyes open to what the others are doing at all.” (p. 90) An obstacle to competition is any deviance from the assumptions of the perfect competition model.

The layman’s definition of competition is the opposite, a rivalrous process of trying to do better than one’s competitors. The market process theory’s definition of competition is closer to the layman’s; competition is “the active process of offering the market opportunities which one believes are better than those others are able or willing to offer.” (p. 96).

In market process theory, an obstacle to competition is anything that prevents participants from offering opportunities to the market (restricted entry). The only possible barriers to entry are the use of force (including government restrictions) and monopolized access to some resource. Pure entrepreneurship is always competitive because it requires no resources.

In orthodox theory, monopoly is a firm’s monopoly over a product. The concepts of the firm and the industry are essential, and substitutability of products raises problems. Monopoly is present whenever a firm faces a downward-sloping demand curve. Monopoly is inefficient because it causes a smaller output to be produced than perfect competition would. Welfare appraisal requires looking at immediate allocation of resources.

In market process theory, monopoly is a resource owner’s monopoly over a resource. The mere fact that a producer is the sole producer of a given product, or that a producer faces downward-sloping demand, does not imply monopoly. A sole producer without sole access to a resource is under as much competitive pressure as anyone else. A monopolist could even face horizontal demand (for example, if he does not realize that the product produced with his monopolized resource is a superior one). At the entrepreneurial level, the demand curve is not a given, and so its shape is irrelevant. The industry and the firm are irrelevant to competition and monopoly, and competition and monopoly are irrelevant to the firm (which is an economizer).

Monopoly is inefficient in market process theory is it causes a resource to be underutilized. Welfare appraisal must consider the long-term effects of the monopoly on the market process. Monopoly does not capture profits, but rents. The monopolist need not product using his resource; he could instead hire out to the market (receiving a higher price than if he were not a monopolist).

Quality is an economic variable as much as price and quantity. Product differentiation may exist at any point simply because the market is not in equilibrium (just as more than one price may exist at one time), and not because of any lack of competition (as is claimed by orthodox models of imperfect competition). The orthodox model of monopolistic competition is inherently flawed because it assumes both product differentiation (leading to profits) and free entry (which should eliminate profits).

The results of assessing monopoly often depend on whether the short- or long- run is examined. Monopoly can result from initial endowments created by the institutional setting, in which case profits and disadvantages should be attributed to the institutions. Monopoly can be the result of entrepreneurial effort, in which case profits can be attributed either to the monopoly position (short-run view) or to the entrepreneurial effort (long-run view). A quasi-monopoly can be the result of an entrepreneur being the first to exploit an opportunity when entry takes time; in this case the entrepreneur has a temporary monopoly while others begin to assemble the resources to compete, and this monopoly can be viewed the same way as the entrepreneurially-gained monopoly.

Kirzner’s assertion that neoclassical always insists on instantaneous equilibrium as a market phenomenon is not completely true. Neoclassical economists introduce market and natural prices to explain non-equilibrium condition and equilibrating tendencies of the market.

With perfect knowledge, everyone knows which offer is best, so that competition ceases, and equilibrium exists. With imperfect knowledge, profit opportunities exist in the market. All such opportunities consist of price differentials; a good (or bundle of inputs) can be bought at a lower price than it (or its product) can be sold. Entrepreneurship is alertness to unnoticed price opportunities. Entrepreneurs exploit these opportunities, and through competition with each other, eliminate them. The market process is inherently entrepreneurial because individuals learn from their participation in the market.

With perfect knowledge, there is no scope for competition or entrepreneurship. The theory of perfect competition, which assumes perfect information, has no relation to competition (the process), except possibly as the result of competition, after the process has completed its course.

Evaluation

Kirzner’s model as developed has shown that the assumptions on the basis of which the theories of competition and monopoly are based upon are insufficient and draws analysis away from reality. So his model as described in the book is based on the “market process” rather than “market equilibrium. (p. 212) He further asserts the importance of ‘welfare maximization’ and ‘social allocation’ which has been overlooked in the previous models. But once we look closely at the neoclassical market approach, we discover its many similarities with the Kirzner’s equilibrating tendencies of the market and its rivalrous competition condition. What surprises us is the lack of explanation from the neoclassical about the imaginative and creative forces of the market that has to destroy the old and build the new in order to maintain the equilibrating tendencies character. Therefore we conclude that the Austrian market process in general and the Kirzner’s entrepreneurial discovery specifically, instead of contrasting, actually complement and enrich the neoclassical and the mainstream approach.

Reference

Kirzner, I. M. Competition and Entrepreneurship, Chicago: University of Chicago, 1973.

More related papers Related Essay Examples
Cite This paper
You're welcome to use this sample in your assignment. Be sure to cite it correctly

Reference

IvyPanda. (2021, October 28). Competition and Entrepreneurship by Kirzner Review. https://ivypanda.com/essays/competition-and-entrepreneurship-by-kirzner-review/

Work Cited

"Competition and Entrepreneurship by Kirzner Review." IvyPanda, 28 Oct. 2021, ivypanda.com/essays/competition-and-entrepreneurship-by-kirzner-review/.

References

IvyPanda. (2021) 'Competition and Entrepreneurship by Kirzner Review'. 28 October.

References

IvyPanda. 2021. "Competition and Entrepreneurship by Kirzner Review." October 28, 2021. https://ivypanda.com/essays/competition-and-entrepreneurship-by-kirzner-review/.

1. IvyPanda. "Competition and Entrepreneurship by Kirzner Review." October 28, 2021. https://ivypanda.com/essays/competition-and-entrepreneurship-by-kirzner-review/.


Bibliography


IvyPanda. "Competition and Entrepreneurship by Kirzner Review." October 28, 2021. https://ivypanda.com/essays/competition-and-entrepreneurship-by-kirzner-review/.

If, for any reason, you believe that this content should not be published on our website, please request its removal.
Updated:
This academic paper example has been carefully picked, checked and refined by our editorial team.
No AI was involved: only quilified experts contributed.
You are free to use it for the following purposes:
  • To find inspiration for your paper and overcome writer’s block
  • As a source of information (ensure proper referencing)
  • As a template for you assignment
1 / 1