Updated:

Agricultural Policies in the EU vs. the US

Exclusively available on Available only on IvyPanda® Written by Human No AI

Abstract

The European Union and the United States form appealing specimens for study because of their obvious incompatibilities or differences in orientation. The appeal is derived from understanding how these different and rival unions manage to trade so well with each other. This is because the EU and the US are nearly each other’s most loyal clients and rivals simultaneously. A quick illustration of such differences is illustrated in the more obvious descriptions or make-up of each respective state. It is the position of this paper concerning the European Union, and the United States, particularly in the light of the political implications on policymaking in the Agricultural Sectors, that both the EU’s Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) and the US’ Farm Bill need some internal adjustments to adapt them to meet the demands of the 21st-century agricultural environment. Such adaptations should achieve the objectives visualized by the policy architects and so breed success according to globally acknowledged measures of managing production.

State intervention can take various forms including service provision, which features the provision of certain ‘public’ goods and services primarily by the state. An example of such public good is communication (Blandford & Orden 2011, p. 100). Secondly, intervention could take the form of regulation, whereby a state or government establishes and/or develops property rights and sets up policies that encourage market competition. Thirdly, the intervention could happen in the form of taxation, which usually targets investors who seek ventures aimed at compensating bearers or who produce negative externalities. There are both theoretical and practical controversies concerning state intervention as the answer to managing market failure (Blandford & Orden 2011). Extreme liberals dismiss the notion of market failure altogether. They insist that there is no such thing as market failure; only the effect of subversion of free markets. Those that are less liberal hold that market failure is irrelevant or that it is simply an interruption in an otherwise flawless free-market mechanism (USDA 2011).

The position taken by this paper gravitates around the moderate theory of Public Choice, which posits that the cost of state intervention far supersedes the costs created by market failure (Baumol, & Oates 1988, p. 215). Market failure is the primary justification for state intervention. In other words, each time federal or state governments interfere with the market they cite market failure as the reason for such usually – more – costly society measures applied to regulate the market. According to proponents of the public choice theory, such intervention measures usually end up draining taxpayers’ resources for the benefit of a few special interest groups.

Introduction

Context/Background to Study

This study hinges on two critical concepts. First are the General Agreement on Tariff and Trade (GATT) agreement and the rounds of negotiations that eventually culminated in the creation of the World Trade Organisation (WTO), which institutionalized world trade and provided a forum for renegotiations concerning multilateral trade agreements among member states (Tancu, Summer 2010, p. 12). The second is the political and socio-economic environment that has formed the watershed in the development of both the European Union and the United States’ agricultural policies. Since WWII left the world licking recovering politically and socio-economically, the members of the international fraternity determined the need for an international overseer of world trade (Tancu, Summer 2010, p. 10).

Initially, this role was taken up by the GATT agreement, but as the political and socio-economic context that had advised the initial structure of GATT evolved, so did the agreement in a round of negotiations. Of relevance to this dissertation is the Uruguay round of agreements held in 1994. This was because it marked the unification of agricultural policy and the formation of the WTO in 1995 (Tancu, Summer 2010, p. 21). The Agreements on Agriculture had the theme of reduced tariffs and non-tariff barriers to trade as well as state interference in the agricultural market, which had led to the failure of the GATT agreement as a regulatory instrument.

The primary cause of this failure of GATT was the permissiveness of the instrument in terms of lax subsidy provisions due to contracting states’ customized policies that catered for their national interests. In allowing this lack of uniformity, GATT opened a loophole for the respective states to institutionalize unsustainable policies. This led to discord and the agricultural sectors of most contracting partners suffered greatly, save for the European Union (EU) and the United States (US) (Tancu, Summer 2010, p. 33). Subsequently, over the past two decades, more variables have come into play in the agricultural policy section such as the sustainability of the environment and the use of biofuels. These being new developments, the EU and the US agricultural policies must be reviewed to study how they respectively handle matters in their jurisdictions and by so doing introduce these insights into the public domain for all other interested parties to review and consider for adoption.

Justification of research methods

Secondary research

Secondary research is the body of research findings, results, discussions, and analysis that has already been collected in previous studies related to the current topic under review by the researcher. In this dissertation, the primary methodology in the application was the secondary analysis of qualitative data, which refers to the use of existing research results to answer research questions that differ from those which were addressed in the referential research (Long-Sutehall, Sque, & Addington-Hall 2010, p. 341). This type of research has primarily been used in social and health studies to expose sensitive data, as well as in policy review studies to trace the genesis and evolution of policies. It was the preferred mode of study in the current dissertation because, first, it is both inexpensive and time-saving as compared to full-blown field research that requires extensive budgets to accommodate data collection and travel expenses. This is especially significant when considered from the point of view of short deadlines for under and postgraduate students’ dissertations. Secondly, it qualifies to be an avenue that offers prospects of creating a new perspective, therefore, giving weight to already existing spheres of knowledge.

Comparative Method

The matter of agricultural policy considerations in the United States and the European Union is a sociological concept. As such, comparison as a modality of enhancing understanding is indispensable (Mills, Van de Bunt, & de Bruijn, 2006, p. 622). The main justification for this method of study is the pursuit of similarities and variance between social entities and the reason why one may be doing this can vary. However, in this dissertation, the researcher’s purpose for seeking out similarities and variances between the EU and the US agricultural policies was driven by a need to understand the status of legislation and recommend improvement options for any dysfunctionality.

This hypothesis makes sense for use in this dissertation because as noted above, the objective of the study is to compare the agricultural policies of the United States and the European Union based on, among others, the premise that the effectiveness of the policy will be determined following the universally acknowledged elements of agricultural prowess. With this in mind, it will be necessary to conduct a brief survey of the political climate in both the European Union and the United States, particularly concerning the succession of office and the change of policy (Commission of the European Communities (CEC) 1991). Now, it is noteworthy that the researcher postulates that the European Union is far better placed to enact and implement policies more effectively than the United States, whose governance keeps changing with each election term.

Aims and objectives of the research

This study aims to analyze and draw comparisons between the distinct characteristics of agricultural policies in the European Union and the United States of America. These two provide many opportunities for exploration concerning agricultural policies among the developed nations primarily because standing together, the EU and the US make up for 60 percent of government-imposed agricultural-sector controls among the developed nations throughout the world (Bernstein, Cooper, & Claassen 2011, p. 67). However, when explored separately, these two territories have very distinct characteristics, which distinction forms the foundational premise of this dissertation. Among the differences that set apart, the US and the EU are their currencies, whereby Europeans use the Euro while Americans use the Dollar. The rate of exchange of the dollar against the Euro fluctuates and it is, therefore, difficult to predict their relationship except within a wide range. Consequently, tracking commodities or infrastructure costs could be impeded by exchange rate fluctuations. This reduces the predictability of balance of payment measures taken by the respective governments and administration to ensure the equitable distribution of resources across the board (Brandford, Josling, & Bureau 2011).

The second matter that requires special consideration is the respective budgetary constraints that accost each nation block. Budgetary stringencies are a poignant matter in decision formulation by policymakers in any jurisdiction. If the funding that has accumulated or been set aside for specific use by the agricultural sector falls short of the stakeholders’ expectations or need, this deficiency will reflect in the quality of the outcomes of the policies (Blandford, & Orden 2011, p. 99).

In this analysis, the term European Union or EU will be used in general to refer to the member states of the European Union convention, including Romania and Bulgaria, which are the latest additions to the EU27 (Josling 2008). The United States, on the other hand, will refer to the federal sanctity of the United States of America as opposed to the expected distinction between various states, except in instances where such specificity is deemed necessary.

When reviewing any agricultural sector’s policy status, whether, for purposes of scouring for faults or constructive improvement reasons, it is critical to know what methodology is preferred by the policymakers at hand to distinguish preference. In most instances, policymakers will go one of two ways, either to favor rural or local economic development or to prefer the product or commodity development or promotion, which is often enhanced by factoring in farmers’ income and providing for a flexible safety net to cover the same (Baumol & Oates 1988, p. 213). Consequently, irrespective of the motivation or circumstances surrounding any policymaking, these two options are the traditional resort points for policymakers in the EU and the US.

Finally, the average plot size for a farm in the United States is 418 acres compared with the smaller average of 22 hectares in the European Union. This parameter gives an initial understanding of the value of output experienced by each union, specifically 214.76 billion Euros for the United States and 304 billion Euros for the European Union (Brandford, Josling, & Bureau 2011, p. 4). Similarities between the EU and Us agricultural policies are minimal and they include the orientation towards a free market for agricultural products that is similar to other industries’ commodities and an inclination towards more sustainable agricultural practices.

Importance of the proposed research

In light of this comparison, a thorough analysis of the symbiosis of these two agricultural systems will reveal possible solutions to some of the problems that afflict other trading partners as far as agriculture is concerned. The analysis will thereby grant justification to this research, which is aimed at discovering a solution for international trading partners that are currently impeded from furthering healthy trade due to barriers and other obstacles that make trading across borders unappealing. Additionally, such an analysis will point out the various weaknesses in both the US and the EU policies and conclude with a suggestion of possible solutions that would be useful and effective in elevating the standard of policymaking across the board.

Summary and outline of the proposed research topic

This research project is aimed at reaching a solution for international traders in the agricultural sector based on the mechanisms that have been tried and tested as evidenced by the harmonious relations between the United States and the European Union. To achieve this, the paper looks at the latter as a block of nations rather than picking on particular members for comparative purposes. The research will majorly be conducted via literature review, which means that the methodology is qualitative although quantitative research will be applied in the analysis of data culminating in mixed research. The theoretical background of this research is discussed in the subsequent section. Notably, the research gravitates around policy considerations as opposed to any other variable as being the most likely cause of this mutuality between the United States and the European Union.

Research Questions

  1. What is the effectiveness of the European Union’s and the US’ agricultural policies in the light of the desired objectives of policy architects as well as the current global gauges of measuring agricultural success?
  2. Depending on which bloc’s policy system is superior, what are the proposed methods that the inferior bloc can use to elevate its performance to match the superiority of the rival bloc?

Methodology

The already-established literature research concerning the agricultural policy sector is immense. However, in this dissertation, the aim is simply to compare and contrast the agricultural policies and their effectiveness of the United States and the European Union. Consequently, that will form the bulk of the literature review. Additionally, the research will extend to theoretical considerations concerning policy formulation and sustenance. It will also review data on the various methodologies that are applicable in the analysis of collected data as well as the formation of conclusions and recommendations.

Methods

This dissertation is primarily based on the findings of a literature review and, since in the field of agricultural policy, the databank is a very extensive, comprehensive, and precise analysis of the information acquired. The procedure for data collection was very elaborate. The researcher went into the World Wide Web and keyed in the terms, “AGRICULTURAL POLICIES IN THE UNITED STATES AND IN THE EUROPEAN UNION.” This yielded 144,000,000 results. Therefore, the next action was to open through the first 300 PDF documents available to scan their content and gauge their relevance. At this point, it became apparent that most of the data available were either superficial or inaccurate.

For example, some sources had only half-page content, and specifically the abstract, meaning that the study could not rely on it in deriving the required content of this paper. Other sources addressed narrowly the required content since their major goal was not the one suggested by the entered terms. This caused the researcher to look into other more reliable sources, namely EBCOHOST and EMERALD. Eventually, there were 150 relevant documents found and so the study began. Carefully following the outline stipulated from the outset, the researcher conducted a thorough review of the available research taking care to make comprehensive notes on the information collected about both US and the EU agricultural policies. The study considered theoretical information that forms the background during policy consideration and the political element in the formulation of agricultural policy. This culminated in a manuscript of 80 pages, which was then compiled and typed out.

The analysis of the results was by the simple comparison of the information collected between the United States and the European Union. This yielded a close correlation in the evolution of agricultural policies between the two unions while also indicating distinctive differences that will appear in the findings, with a further discussion in the results section. Finally, based on the analysis of the information collected, the researcher concluded and made recommendations concerning the nature and distinctions of agricultural policies in both nation-state blocs.

The US Agricultural Policy

The origin of the United States’ policy concerning agriculture was during the Great Depression of the late 1930s. At that time, close to 20 percent of Americans were rural dwellers subsisting on agriculture for a living. This explains why the original objective of the policy was to support commodity prices and rural incomes. Since those early days, the United States and the European Union have been trading partners. Having learned from the Great Depression, and participating only towards the end of WWII, the United States was better equipped to deal with the food shortages that plagued the post-war world and she exported her products throughout the globe. The European countries were some of her biggest destinations especially in the late 1940s and early 1950s (U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service 2001). However, soon enough, the European Union and the majority of the world pieced together their internal affairs aided by technological advancements and government support for their agricultural sectors, mostly taking the form of price regulations.

Consequently, in the 1960s, the United States found herself lacking several prospective buyers of her produce, and this culminated in the accumulation of stocks in the United States, which in turn affected her economy as the prices decreased due to surplus (Dorward, Fan, Kydd, Lofgren, Morrison, Poulton, Rao, Smith, Tchale, Thorat, Urey, & Wobst, 2004 p. 614). The US farm policy changed reactively to incorporate supply management. Some of the measures that were taken to manage the excessive supplies included the institution of food aid or donation programs both internally and abroad, and monumental acreage planting restrictions. The other aspect is demographic and is demonstrated by the average farm sizes.. In the US, 7.3million farms are used for economic exploitation as opposed to less than 2.2 million farms in the EU (Brandford, Josling, & Bureau, September 2011, p. 3). Additionally, farming in the US is more strictly regulated with restrictions dictating planting and location. For instance, farmers in the EU can readily diversify their products by changing their crops and livestock to accommodate fruit and flowers.

In the1970s, there was a global economic and commodity price crisis. Strategies were put in place to solve this by hiking the prices of commodities in a bid to settle farmers’ discontent (Swinbank, & Josling 2012). Noting that the United States had put in place supply management measures, at this stage of history, she did not have enough in store for her consumption and so she had to source from abroad (Heather, & Muller 2006). There was a global reduction in grains and oilseed stocks, which yielded a sharp price hike in global prices of commodities and made agricultural support by governments or states a necessity. This market failure is required to be addressed (Heniff 2010).

The effectiveness of any state intervention measures heavily relies upon the status of the political environment of such a government because it forms the background to which policymakers rely on while creating regulatory policies. To explain this concept further, policy-makers under duress note that good policies formed by a good democratic government are an inadequate public good not enjoyed by most citizens. The cause of this inadequacy is the ignorance of the majority of voters concerning their rights and obligations, as well as the level of acumen they should require of their elected representatives. Additionally, the effectiveness of any formulated policy is further curtailed by the duration of policymakers’ terms, which public choice theorists posit are too short to affect the formulation and implementation of any effective policy (Barnard, Whittaker, Westenbarger, & Ahearn 1997).

Since the policy only lives as long as the term of the instituting policymakers, and new legislators upon taking office often immediately overhaul or amend the policy, regulations do not have the chance to become effective. When policy-making becomes politically based, the respective sectors of the economy initially targeted by such policies are bound to suffer. However, the researcher also warns of the danger of making this assumption considering that, despite the frequent government changes in the United States, some policies, such as those governing agriculture are not necessarily changed with each successive government. The third reason why the cost of the government’s failures surpasses those associated with market failures according to public choice theorists is that special interest groups in society specifically lobby for interests that are only beneficial to them. Among the major theoretical contributors to the concept of government failure are authors like George Stigler, who wrote about what harm private interests can do to regulations; Mancur Olson, who points out the coasters in collective action; and Ann Krueger who wrote on the Compensation – seeking tendencies depicted by most bureaucrats (Koning 2006).

The United States reacted by instituting commodity price targets that were directly proportional to the cost of production. This meant that they had a self-inflating effect on the income generated to farmers according to the costs invested in production (Fan, & Rao, 2003 p. 466). In return, this facilitated the institution of support outlays and concomitant agricultural output free from the variations of market conditions. Consequently, the 1980s were a repeat of history with the accumulation of stocks due to generous price and income supports (U.S. Farm Bill and the EU Common Agriculture Policy at Crossroads A Global Dialogue on U.S., Canadian and EU Agriculture policies 2007). It was alarming that most of these stocks were state-owned. The result was a significant reduction in commodity prices and the increase of budgetary pressures for reform, which quadrupled financial subsidies.

In 1985, the US Farm Bill (P.L. 99-198), was enacted and at this juncture, it is important to note that the nature of this farm bill, known in full as the Omnibus Farm Bill is transitory. This means that every five to seven years, legislators are required to comprehensively review the status of farming in the United States, then proceed to make amendments to the farm bill, which continues to subsist across various administrations (Brandford, Josling, & Bureau, September 2011). The US farm bills are an elaborate instrument that so far has managed to sustain her agricultural sector through various tough situations, but only barely. Presently, the debates racking the country over the issue of ethanol regulations, safety net provisions, direct payment equitability, and other farm bill related matters are clear evidence of the precarious nature of this policy. Additionally, the fact that the policy is still a bill in transition (i.e. not a law) gives it a quality of temporariness, which attracts a lax attitude in adherence to its dictates. Added to the fact that the government of the United States is democratic, meaning that each succession may mean a radical change to the existing policies, the farm bill is at best a very volatile regulation that requires a semblance of permanence, which quality it can emulate from the EU CAP policy.

In 1985, the US Farm Bill provided for a reduction of the Commodity Credit Corporation’s (CCC) price support loan rates; the inactivation through the freezing of income support target prices, and program yields that were used in the calculation of acreage payments. It also provided for special marketing plans for rice and cotton to come out of the traditional mentality of ‘public’ goods, which were being primarily owned and controlled by the government. The 1990 Farm Bill (P. L. 101-624) was responsible for reducing the amount of land that had been initially allocated for the income support payments (Brandford, Josling, & Bureau, September 2011). The 1996 Farm Bill (P. L. 104 – 127) was the first in the history of farm bills that was aimed at the orientation of the agricultural sector towards a more liberalized and less government-controlled sector.

This was in line with the 1994 (April 15) Uruguay Round Agreement on Agriculture (Blandford, & Josling 2011, p. 45). That agreement had been signed by most of the member states of the World Health Organisation (WTO) and they pledged to reduce and eventually completely eradicate government or state control on agriculture. The result was that the member states pledged to reduce domestic supports, the use of export subsidies, and to improve the access to their markets through tariff reduction and lax border control measures (U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service 2001). Therefore, the 1996 Farm Bill was the embodiment of the liberalization of the agriculture policy spirit. It provided for the elimination of acreage reduction programs, (ARPS); planting restrictions, which had required farmers in specific regions or with specific plot sizes to plant specifically state-mandated crops (Dennis, 2007). It also eliminated those grain reserves that were under the ownership of individual farmers. Supported by the state, it replaced target –plan deficiency payment plans with direct payments. Finally, it incorporated other major crops into the special marketing loan provisions that were initially only available for rice and cotton production since the 1985 farm bill.

Thus, it is evident that, over the last two decades, the United States has moved from the initial trend in policymaking, which was primarily aimed at promoting trade-distorting practices, especially commodity price and income support, towards an orientation to less distorting support of non-commodities. These include rural development, which includes infrastructure, community projects, and business development, and even bioenergy, and farmland conservation or “agri-environmental” programs (Bureau, & Louis-Pascal2009). Consequently, the level of US domestic support for such liberalized ventures had shot up to 88 percent by 2008.. The Orthodox Economic Theory holds that market failure occurs when the procedures applied during production or resource allocation yield an inadequate reflection of costs or benefits in the prices of goods and services and consequently to less – than – effective macroeconomic decision making by economic agents or imperfect competition in case of sub-optimal market structures (Blandford, & Josling 2011, p. 45).

Manifestations of market failures include public goods, which are immune to market price mechanisms because they are non – rival or non – exclusive. Non – rivalry refers to the impossibility of depleting the supply for some consumers simply by increasing the supply to others and so, in a way, they are inexhaustible by natural free-market mechanisms. Non – exclusivity refers to the fact that the private sector has no mandate to ban the consumption of such goods or services thus changing consumption patterns (Caldwell 2004, p. 23). Another example of a market failure is the persistence of entry barriers, which maintain some industries at infancy by restricting the entrance of competition due to factors such as the requirement for high investment (DFID 2004, p. 790).

In case of such market failures, the state, following the doctrine of paternalism will intervene by applying certain economic tools to regulate the market and attempt to return it to normalcy. The use of ‘attempt’ in the previous sentence is calculated because the government can’t return the market to the same position as it was before the failure. In the majority of circumstances, the economy will have shrunk slightly as manifested by the increase in the number of unemployed persons or the level of interest rates (American Farmland Trust 2002). Additionally, during the process of intervention, prices usually leap up or down, depending on the type of shock that has caused market failure. Although this change may just be temporary (where ‘temporary’ does not necessarily mean that they will resume in a short while but that eventually, they will resume), the result is never the same as the starting point. Therefore, market failures are a primary justification for state intervention in a bid to restore economic efficiency and correct markets’ functionality.

The formulation of policies aimed at the regulation of agricultural practices at both state and federal levels is a representation of state intervention in market regulation. State intervention is largely frowned upon in most economic forums because the overall view held by the majority of market analysts is that state intervention does more harm than good in a market that is apparently in need of regulation. Of course, those that hold this view are the major proponents of the ‘laisez faire’ doctrine or free markets and they have a lining of Marxism lacing their arguments (International Food & Agricultural Trade Policy Council 2011). It is important to note here that the agricultural sector is not like most traditional markets wherein state intervention can so easily be dispensed with because the adverse effects of the opposite of state intervention are more poignantly felt by all in the society due to the nature of the sector and the overall dependency on the same (Dennis 2007).

Currently, in the United States, the agricultural debate is centered on the matter of the ‘safety net’. The definition of this term is controversial but the Obama Administration has pointed out that it has to do with the contingency allowance set apart for use upon the occurrence of bad weather or poor prices. These two adversities are likely to create problems for farmers; therefore, the government has set aside a fund to ensure that in case of their occurrence, farmers are cushioned against the harsh effects of the same. Farmers are speculating that the safety net will come in handy when there are unforeseen price reductions for commodities leading to a replication of the Great Depression. This would mean that the safety net is likely to be an application for longer than the aforementioned temporary or transitory period. A justification for such an argument is the recent price reductions that rocked the nation between 1998 and 2002. As observed above, the United States has put in place measures to conserve and preserve working lands, which were initially arable land used for crop production. The way they go about achieving this conservation objective is by reforestation, conversion into wetlands and grasslands depending on the initial geography and demographical characteristics of the land. Consequently, the lack of state intervention does not have a very strong case when it comes to the agricultural sector.

However, it is also noteworthy that despite this perceived ‘necessity’ of state intervention in the regulation of the agricultural sector to keep it from sinking, much to the detriment of the society as a whole, a more pressing need to carefully consider the procedural manner of or, better yet, the alternative avenues to state intervention. One such consideration yields ‘parastatal -ism’ as an option to state monopoly concerning traditionally labeled ‘public’ goods and services (American Farmland Trust 2002). The United States’ policy environment is highly dependent upon the political climate of the country. The United States is proving to be more reactive than proactive in terms of policy enforcement especially in the light of terrorist development. Concerning the United States Farm Bills, constant reviewing is an indication of political influence that may be detrimental to the integrity of the Bills. With each successive government, it is unwise to keep changing the bill, which is why the Obama administration is commendable in terms of having extended the validity of the Farm Bill that had been reformed in 2008 and was meant to expire by early June 2011, to September 2013 (Brandford, Josling, & Bureau 2011). This extension was allowed by the House of Representatives and the Senate in order to allow time to carry on with debates regarding the validity of the Bill. As the ongoing deliberations have revealed, the Bio Fuels policy concerning ethanol production is inherently flawed and would require for the incorporation of additional clauses or provisions to cater for the newer recommendations.

One such recommendation was for the specificity of prescriptive policies concerning the amounts of support allocated to each individual subsector. On the United States’ farm bills, two matters stand out, the first being the safety net program. Currently, there is a lot of stipulation concerning how the safety net funds will be disbursed. Various groups have diverse opinions concerning the way the matter can be approached. Some farmers posit that the safety net program ought to cover both the ramifications of bad weather and sudden price reductions. The effect of such an interpretation is that the fund would have a very wide array of possible situations that would justify its disbursement and defeat its original purpose. To avoid this trap, the researcher posits that the fund is divided into two endowments. One should deal with disaster relief, and this would include all climate-related eventualities. The other part of the fund would deal with economic market failures.. However, in so doing, the fund should be formulated such that it is well protected from any eventualities such as price reductions, and farmers should be required to contribute to it regularly.

Secondly, the farmers themselves need to improve their financial situation by entering into systemic business plans that are aimed at ensuring that they are covered in case of such eventualities. Such plans should be very comprehensive and an example of the components needed to ensure their applicability is the provision of insurance programs and pension schemes among other services. The purpose of the 1994 World Trade Organisation Agreement on Agriculture was to abolish state intervention into the agricultural market and in effect making the agricultural sector similar to other industries in terms of regulation. However, these agreements worked to reduce market intervention but they left the agricultural system handicapped to handle its affairs since it had become accustomed to spoon-feeding by the state (Bernstein, Cooper, & Claassen 2011, p. 72. To counter this, it is prudent to ensure that farmers become self-reliant as a sector. To achieve this, some of the possible means applicable include the institution of individual farm income stabilization accounts (FISA) (Schnepf, & Hanrahan 2011, p. 66). These would be instrumental in the creation of parastatals so that there is a level of cooperation between the state and individual farmers.

However, it is unsafe to assume that all the United States’ policies are reactive but for those on emerging matters (Josling 2008). On that note, the new research that is available throughout the world on the functioning of market systems suggests a new way of doing things. In this new research, the issue of macroeconomic coordination processes that are an economic phenomenon suggests that perhaps the way to deal with crises caused by market failure is not to intervene as the government or state, through traditional means of either financial or monetary policies (inherently faulted). Rather, the best way is to look into other more sustainable means of correction (Heather, & Muller 2006).

One such alternative is the use of parastatals, which are both government-owned and individually owned. In the agricultural sector, there are those products and services that the government will usually endeavor to regulate such as meat and pyrethrum production. Such produce thus becomes ‘public goods’ in light of the state control vested in the same and when this happens, the rest of the population is discouraged from producing them. Consequently, the state maintains some sort of monopoly over these and this is an unproductive type of state control. Failure under such a system is inevitable because the primary producer is the state and corruption will soon tear such a system to the ground (Swinbank, & Josling 2012). A good example of such an eventuality is China, which is currently battling corruption within her links and gaining success at a discouragingly slow momentum due to how deeply entrenched the vice is. To avoid such a fate as China, it would be prudent to diversify production and encourage external investors from the private sectors as well as NGOs.

In the United States, the government has already started branching out of the traditional public goods and services mentality and has embraced the idea of parastatals in quite a several sectors including energy production and supply as well as transportation (European Commision 2011). However, concerning agriculture, this monopoly is still apparent in the favorable treatment of some products than others, such as particular cereals or livestock brands.

Whereas it would be very imprudent to require that all the sub-sectors within the agricultural sector comply receive equal funding or support considering the difference in productivity and produce across the board, it wise to consider just which sectors require how much support about the updated research on productivity and sustainability.

For instance, the agricultural practices that are known to be productive of high levels of renewable energies are a worthy investment for support by the government or state because this would be doubly profitable (National Academy of Sciences 2009). That comprises a majority of the cereal producers and other related fields such as livestock production, which is productive of biogas or biomass. In the United States, agricultural policy programs affect various segments or targets including the producers, the consumers, and the agricultural sector in general. It does this by proffering direct and indirect support (Schoonover, & Muller 2006). For instance, there is a federal agricultural support policy that provides commodity and price support, agricultural trade and marketing, and consumer food assistance, which is in the form of welfare programs such as food stamps. The Congressional Budget office postulates a likely amount of $ 8.3 billion to be spent each year during the life of the 2008 Farm Bill (FY2008 – FY2012) and $6.9 billion per annum between FY2011 andFY2015 (Krissoff, Ballenger, Dunmore,& Gray 1996, p. 738). However, it is noteworthy that the amounts anticipated for the period between 2011 and2015 are likely to be higher because of the increment of the quotas that are eligible for welfare programs as well as due to the adverse economic conditions besetting the nation.

Concerning the conservation, rural development, and nutritional field as specific sectors targeted in the policy reform since 2008, it is noteworthy that since the institution of the 1985 bill, the United States has been attempting to encourage farmers to adopt and implement agricultural policies that are sustainable to the environment (Kydd, & Dorward 2001, p. 471). The USDA is the key driver for sustainability and it emphasizes land retirement and easement programs. This refers to the practice of converting crop production lands or formerly arable lands into forest reserves, grasslands, or wetlands depending on the original type of geography before agriculture began to be practiced on the land. Such lands are referred to as ‘working lands’. Additionally, in the 2008 farm bill, there are provisions for bioenergy production. This means that the ethanol production that has both provided for and threatened the United States economy is provided for, although the integrity of these provisions are largely a matter of controversial debates among various interest groups (Yano, Blandford, & Surry 2011).

Concerning the welfare program, known commonly as stamps, Title IV of the 2008 Farm Bill (110 – 246) provides for several domestic food and nutrition and commodity distribution programs such as the Supplemental Nutritional Assistance Program, SNAP that was formally known as food stamps. The estimated costs for the support of these programs by the CBO is $ 37.8 billion per annum although as noted above, these figures are likely to change due to economic conditions and increased eligibility (OECD 2012). Finally, the rural development, conservation, and nutrition programs are not as dynamic as the commodity price and income support programs because they seem rather harmless or benign or simply meritorious depending on what point of view one has, either social or political. For this reason, they rarely change as often as the more dynamic commodity price and income support programs.

The EU Agricultural Policy

It is important to note that with the European Union, agricultural policy has been developed at both national and supranational levels. That is to say that the final EU policy for agriculture, which is in the COMMON AGRICULTURAL POLICY post-2013 is in consideration for both the regional and the respective national regulation of agriculture for respective member states (Commission of the European Communities (CEC) 1991). Considering that the composite members of the European Union feature various legally, economically, socially, and politically distinct states, it is safe to indicate that the harmony depicted by the final regulatory legislation over agriculture is truly stunning. The EU policy on agriculture is a sectoral public policy that looks into issues that fall outside the jurisdiction or reach or ambit of free-market mechanisms. However, it was not always peachy and it still needs further attention but the COMMON AGRICULTURAL POLICY has its roots in the early 1960s (Josling 2008). Immediately after WWII, the impact of the lack of fortification in the agricultural sector that was especially apparent with the starvation that accosted Europe triggered the search for a lasting dynamic solution.

Whereas the agricultural sector was still a significant force in the economy as evidenced by its great Capacity to employ, the brunt of starvation during the war was still a fresh wound and the respective legislators felt the need to institutionalize agricultural policies for future safety. This was the genesis of the COMMON AGRICULTURAL POLICY. COMMON AGRICULTURAL POLICY receives its backing from the Treaty of Rome’s development of common market systems, particularly for the six (6) member states of the European Economic Community (EEC), namely Belgium, France, Republic of Federal Germany, Lisbon, Italy, and Netherlands (European Commission 2010). The primary objectives of this common market included economic and social integration as well as the promotion of sustainable economic development among others. In 1993, the EEC split into the European Union and the European Community. 1992 marked the genesis of the change or reform associated with agriculture in the European Union.

The trend began to shift from a general pattern of supporting cereal and key livestock farming via state intervention through state intervention. State intervention would usually take the form of price regulation and export subsidies (Duffy, Taylor, Cain, & Young 1994, p. 322). However, with the policy shift, the European Union began to focus on direct payments to farmers that were made independent and irrespective of the current produce or output. The effect of this inclination by the European Union has been to appease the farmers in terms of stability of income. The way this worse is better understood if reviewed with the background of pre-1992. As indicated in the history of the formation of EU policies. The journey of policy review has been rather lengthy and it began with a unified approach by the founders of the EEC to integrate trade and economies in the region. At this level, through the Treaty of Rome, which as will be indicated later became incorporated into the Treaty of Lisbon, which in turn granted perpetual validity to the Common Agricultural Policy, COMMON AGRICULTURAL POLICY, had a two-faced effect on the international arena and the regional bloc that defined the EEC (Ellis, & Biggs 2001, p. 440).

The first of these impacts was the increased economic productivity of the region. This was primarily accomplished using price regulations, which were engendered to ensure that the exports from the European Union were more expensive. In other words, a price hike was orchestrated (Ferrer, & Kaditi 2010). Additionally, the support for agriculture increased suddenly especially in light of policy regulations that were favorable to agricultural success. Consequently, farmers, who were initially marginalized and their dominance in the European Union threatened despite the noted importance of agriculture began to enjoy good incomes that further boosted their morale and production as well as productivity increased.

However, the reaction in the international arena was not so positive. Key trading partners of the European Union began to drop out and find substitutes for products that were initially primarily of a European Union origin. Those that remained in trade reduced their share capacity in terms of investments in the European Union and the European Union became some sort of international Trade pariah. This would have been bearable if only it had not extended to other sectors of trade that were non – agricultural but unfortunately, with the amazing results being recorded by the agricultural sector, other industries and sectors in the EU had also followed suit and increased their prices overnight for no apparent reason (European Commision 2011). The result was minor international inflation and as those go, the joy enjoyed by the EU was short-lived. As partners continued to pull out, affronted rivals and competitors began to pay in like by hiking the prices of raw products. Consequently, the cost of production in the European Union shot up (International Food & Agricultural Trade Policy Council 2011). This meant that the only available solutions for the European Union were to cut down on their prices and mend fences with their trading partners, or maintain the high prices and risk destabilizing the global economy as other suppliers and producers throughout the world hiked their prices to cope with the inflation.

Being the paragon of ethics that it is, the EU buckled and lowered its prices across the Board. This gave a semblance of cooperation and the rest of her trading partners followed suit as well. The international players had been appeased. However, the farmers would soon become discontent yet again especially in light of the freshly enjoyed economic profits of the inflation that were now cut down and as these factors work, the new level was far below the previous levels of input. This created a dangerous situation in the European Union where agriculture hangs in the balance and at a high risk of being sabotaged by irate farmers. Something needed to put in place (Grindle, & Thomas 1991, p. 78). Thus, in 1992, the reforms on the COMMON AGRICULTURAL POLICY were a welcome relief. For instance, Common Agricultural Policies (CAP) has governed the European Union since the late 1960s whereas the United States has been under the Farm Bills that officially came into being in 1985. Secondly, the European Union additionally relies on legislation from the Common External Tariff whereas the United States is singly loyal to its Farm Bills statute, with minimal references to related environmental legislation that are not part of the farm bills. With the EU, the CAP forms the definitive policy on agriculture in Europe and any other related policies are incorporated as an addendum to the same, case in point being the 1992 MacSharry Reforms and the Agenda 2000 and 2003 Reforms (Schnepf, & Hanrahan 2011 p. 3).

Considering the European Union’s inability to balance between the international arena and her domestic arena, the new reforms were both genius and costly. However, they are a clear indication that there can indeed be an alternative to state intervention as the perceived only option when faced with market failure. The near-collapse of the European Union’s economy is also a clear indication that state intervention is not necessarily as peachy as one may easily assume.

One of the key changes that heralded this new era of policy reform was the substitution of market intervention to regulate prices by support for direct domestic payments and export subsidies. What this means is that whereas initially, the agricultural arena of the EEC was in the form of a market system that regularly suffered state intervention, it now became different in that the farmers would be paid directly by the government regardless of the season’s output or the farmers’ yield (Krissoff, Ballenger, Dunmore, & Gray 1996, p. 38). This meant that the effects of global changes in price that were often detrimental to farmers’ income and morale were now cushioned by the various governments as these would swallow up any rapids in the global economy and provide the farers with a regular dependable income that was reasonably fair. This appeased the farmers as the reliability of the state was reinstated and so agriculture picked up again. Concerning the wisdom behind this kind of arrangement in terms of the governments’ capacity to absorb the losses, that aspect was managed by the fact that the global agricultural market was a free market that would straighten out any market failures over time and without need for intervention, usually towards economic growth. Consequently, this provided some sort of an umbrella cover for the respective governments concerning long-term stability.

The European Union has a record of greater Agricultural support than the United States from the annals of history (Ackrill, & Kay 2004, p. 2). Of course, it is relevant to define agricultural support and so about the rural development and nutritional assistance, the World Trade Organisation, WTO indicates in its notification data that between 2006 and 2007, the European union’s governmental support totaled $119.7 billion per annum while the United States’ recorded a support of $ 82.6 billion. This translates to a ration of 1.4: 1 (Reichert 2006). Concerning market-distorting genres of direct farm subsidies, the European Union recorded $ 36.9 billion worth of support while the United States recorded a paltry $10.1 billion worth of support. Although both unions had smaller levels of support, the European Union’s support still outshined the United States’ at a ratio of 3.6: 1 (Mullarkey, Cooper, & Skully 2001, p. 87).

Finally, concerning non-monetary support, which is where policies orient in the form of trade barriers and border measures, the OECD reports that in 2009, the European Union was the greatest reporter of government support in a survey conducted to gauge the levels of agricultural support among developed countries (OECD 2012). The European Union accounted for close to half of its governmental support, at 48 percent, which amounts to $ 120.8 billion. On the other hand, the United States only reported accounting for 12 percent, which translates to $ 30.66 in outlays (Reichert 2006). The European Union and the United States are the world’s largest stockholders although this has not always been the case (Barnard, Whittaker, Westenbarger, & Ahearn 1997, p. 1644). Consequently, they seem to have similar policies concerning the agricultural sector especially for commodity price and income supports, direct payments to farmers, the control of supplies, and border control.

The use of sustainable energy or renewable energy has been encouraged for a while now throughout the globe. However, recorded and institutionalized efforts to promote the use of renewable energy in the European Union date back to 1997. Before 1997, ethanol production was limited to the quantities generated as a by-product of agricultural practice. However, after 1997, the European Union has actively set out to set out the procedure and mandate for protocols to be followed by farmers and other industrial sectors for the promotion and sustenance of renewable energies (Thurston 2005). Close to the dawn of 2000, the European Union passed a mandate that required a replication up of the proportion of renewable fuels used in the home states from a cumulative six (6) percent to another level within a decade. In 2003, the European Union Bio Fuels Directive came to birth, and alongside this policy, the European Union Strategy for Bio Fuels

However, real change concerning Bio Fuels policy was earmarked by the introduction of the Climate Change Package, in 2009. This package comprised of several regulation suggestions including the Directive for Renewable Energy (RED) in 2009 (Potter 1998). RED is primarily responsible for the development of a regional (across the European Union bloc) obligatory target of 10 percent of transport energy coming from renewable sources by 2020 (European Commision 2011). This has been a very elaborate plan and respective member states are expected to comply or face sanctions from the ECJ for non-compliance. Most of the member states in a devolutionary bid have passed domestic legislation to ensure that these directives are complied with. For instance, in the United Kingdom, the domestic legislation in support of electricity energy suppliers requires the suppliers to source at least 10 percent of their total energy from renewable energy (IATP 2009). Failure to comply with this specific regulation culminates in the payment of a fine ‘pay out’ that is a percentage of the total revenue earned from the electricity (Dennis 2007). The sanction that is imposed is usually borne by the consumers and soon enough, discontent consumers will shift to ‘fairer’ electricity suppliers, thus causing a loss of market for the suppliers who fail to comply with the established energy requirements.

In France, a related tax is specifically levied on gasoline. The policy requires that gasoline suppliers mix it with a certain percentage of renewable energy before supply to make it more sustainable to the environment. This is because when gasoline is mixed with certain energy types, it combusts sustainably, breaking down into elements that do not pollute the environment (Keeney, & Muller 2006). Those that fail to comply with this regulation pay the price of taxation, which they would normally pass on to consumers, who would eventually shift their loyalty to more affordable, more sustainable suppliers. In the end, compliance is the more prudent option.

Moreover, RED makes provision for 20 percent of all energy fuels being sourced from renewable energy by 2020 (Ferrer, & Kaditi 2010). This goal would be a 12 percent increment from the eight percent level that was reported in 2009 as the amount of total renewable energy that is used in the EEC. These policies are directly linked to agriculture because the production of this energy is usually through agricultural practice with renewable energies being a mere by-product of such processes. Consequently, in the policy enactment, it would be imperative that the legislators provide incentives for the production of farm produce that is associated with renewable energy sources. However, with CAP, the policymakers have used the direct payments and export subsidies to increase the payment quotas of those farmers whose produce offers renewable energy as a by-product and so that is a viable alternative of an incentive.

Two things come up concerning Bio Fuels Policy. One is that it came up in the spirit of compliance to the Common Agricultural Policy objective of creating a sustainable environment (Keeney, & Muller 2006). The objectives are further outlined in the next portion of this paper. However, it is worth noting that at its incorporation into the Treaty of Lisbon, the CAP objectives included the sustainability of the environment. At the time, it was not so clear that the way to go about the fulfillment of this objective was through Bio Fuels, but with the lapse of time, Bio Fuels were preferable alternatives to non – renewable fuels. Thus, their support began (Swinbank & Josling 2012). The second issue that comes up with that review is the fact that in this particular instance, the European Union is using taxation as a deterrent to prevent non – compliance.

About market systems and specifically common market systems such as the European Union, market failures are inevitable. As mentioned earlier in this paper, in the event of market failure, state intervention is usually viewed as the better option or rather the solution to end up with a regulated or balanced market (Jean-Christophe, & Witzke 2010). However, as already discussed, state intervention is not without its flaws. Flaws are numerous but the one that is by far the most repulsive flaw of state intervention is the destabilization of the economy following the state intervention. This destabilization is usually the result of cyclic perpetuity of market failures, in which cyclic motions are caused by the impossibility of sustainability of the policy objectives (Bureau, & Louis-Pascal 2009).

At the time of the formation of the Common Agricultural Policies, this incompatibility of clauses was one of the major concerns of the founders. The objectives of CAP at its formation included: the enhancement of sustainable economic development, economic cohesiveness, an improvement of the standard of living within the European Union, and Improvement of the relations among member countries (Krueger 1990, p. 19). The BioFuels are in response to the fulfillment of the first objective. Chapter 93 of the Common Agricultural Policies Convention provides for objectives such as increased productivity and secure availability of supplies. It also takes care of the provision of reasonable prices for food to ease consumers’ burden in light of the post-depression era; stabilization of the common markets, and the promotion or assurance of a higher, fairer, living standard (Brandford, Josling, & Bureau 2011).

The established principles that CAP was supposed to bring to success included market unification, which has been achieved commendably, a priority of the community, which is the justification for the initial method of salvaging agriculture in the European Union, namely through price hikes without any regard to for other economic participants. Therefore, it is safe to say that this particular principle may have been done away with. At the very least, it may have been watered down or amended to include the ethical requirement of ‘clean hands’ (Orden, Blandford, & Josling 2011). The equitable principle of clean hands requires that whoever goes to a forum of adjudication for settlement of a dispute (the initiator) bear clean hands or that such a claimant ought not to have instigated the slight.

Now that the agricultural sector has since been secured, what is the next step? To continue in the same line of action would continue to yield similar results as have been harvested for the past 40 years (U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service 2000). It is the position of this paper that, concerning the European Union, and without taking into consideration the facts surrounding the United States, that the European Union’s CAP needs in–house changes. It has to adapt it to the global age as well as the agricultural demands of the billions of human beings populating the earth in the twenty-first century.

Concerning the price hike saga, which, interestingly, was also in time for the joinder of the United Kingdom to the European Union in 1973, the EU did not have clean hands. This jeopardized future claims that the EU may have been required to make to protect the integrity and sustainability of its member’s economies. Consequently, the search for a different alternative to appease the farmers was prudent in the bigger picture. The final principle envisaged in the CAP is financial solidarity and this has so far been achieved to the satisfaction of the policymakers’ vision (Thurston 2005).

Under scrutiny, the above objectives expose a specific vulnerability, which is incompatibility if they were to be followed up simultaneously. Take for instance the reasonable prices of goods and the stability of markets. One can’t achieve both of these noble goals simultaneously using the same tools, in this case, state intervention. If one regulates the prices at the state level, there will be consequences, which will include the changes in the levels of interest rates as well as employment and this automatically destabilizes the economy. The same for the regulation of market stability, this cannot be done without tampering with prices, usually adversely (Bureau, & Louis-Pascal 2009).

Consequently, and in light of these inherent incompatibilities of the proposed policy but still in consideration for the fact that it was expedient that a support system is established for the agricultural sector, the European Court of Justice, (ECJ) granted an advisory opinion on this state of affairs (Josling 2008). The ECJ noted that even though legislation needed to be uniform or inherently sustainable, there was a more pressing need for agricultural sector reform and so this made it possible for the CAP regulation to subsist despite its shortcomings (Wiggerthale 2005). However, since the incorporation of the Treaty of Rome and subsequent listing in the Treaty of Lisbon, the CAP has seen close to four decades, during which time it has fulfilled about 70 percent of its intended objectives. At this point, it is important to ask ourselves whether it is more prudent to go about fulfilling the objectives as it has for the past 40 years especially considering that the justification for procrastination of symmetry in the legal instrument was the need to first secure the agricultural sector.

Currently, the problem that is being faced by the European Union about policy considerations is the escalation of budgetary costs. The budgetary costs that are necessary for the sustenance of the proposed reforms make the proposed CAP incompatible with the established standards for sustainable policies. This is because the regional bloc currently lacks any conclusive means of making a substantial financial contribution to the implementation stage of new policies. As an organ, the European Union is toothless having no say concerning the members’ compliance, except for the charter. This makes it difficult to sustain any policies passed at the EU level and hinges on the voluntary cooperation of members for the fulfillment of enacted policies for the EU (International Food & Agricultural Trade Policy Council 2011). On the members’ level, they counter this problem by transferring the budgetary costs to the consumers and taxpayers, who in return react by civil actions such as strikes’ boycotts, demonstrations, or outright violence including vandalism to government property in the event of extreme measures. Such reactions are detrimental to the motivational base of the legislators who in their opinion, and rightfully so, these policies are supposed to be for the benefit of the public.

Consequently, the question is, “How does the EU solve the crisis that is ‘budgetary costs’?”. This issue is not a new phenomenon for the European Union. In fact, during the circa 1973 price hikes, the state intervention that had taken the form of authorizing these price hikes was in reaction to the market failure that had resulted in escalated budgetary costs. Consequently, since this is the second occurrence in history, the answer should not be automatic state intervention. Instead, those involved should look into other possibilities of attaining market balance and so far, policy reform presents the most viable option

Borrowing from the Public Theorists’ position on the effect of government intervention leads to the use of capitalism as a viable example of the possible turn out of events. Karl Marx’s capitalism, with the hint of materialism, postulates that in a society where a few people in power clutch onto the available resources, the rich will always get richer as the poor get poorer. This is true especially about the European Union under which most of the members, except Germany and a few others, are out rightly capitalistic (Ferrer, & Kaditi 2010).

The effect of such a socio-political and economic background is that those in power, which forms the bulk of the policymakers, will always pass legislation that is favorable to them and those whose interests they hold dear. However, there is a distinction between the European Union and the United States concerning the politics of the ruling government. The European Union has independent countries each with unique political make-ups as opposed to the United States whose independent states are more of provinces than countries with only one president, meaning that the political system across the borders highly meshes and the level of assimilation is rather high.

Policy Comparison and Conclusion

The above research was primarily conducted through the collection and analysis of documented research. As a research methodology, a review of documentation is particularly popular when investigating the genesis and evolution of a concept. In this dissertation, the primary agenda was the comparison of agricultural sector policies of the United States and the European Union. This required the researcher to delve deep into the annals of history to trace the roots that establish the foundation of the respective policies of both the European Union and the United States. Subsequently, the researcher could then trace a path through history spanning the evolution of the policies up to the twenty-first century (Timothy 2007).

This required a thorough review of voluminous literature to sift out irrelevances and remain with the most appropriate data on this topic. Additionally, as the research developed, the researcher found out new sub-topics that were complementary to the main topic, for instance, Bio Fuels Policies, and incorporated them into the dissertation. One of the advantages of review of documentation or secondary research is that the data is already existent and thus is free of bias. When conducting interviews and other surveys for data collection, respondents’ responses can never be free of bias and so an individual researcher’s findings would be inherently flawed. When reviewing documentation from other research, the level of bias is minimized and the accuracy of the documentation is greater than in the former scenario.

However, this method of research has its shortcomings and one of them is the occasional irrelevance of data collected. In the present dissertation, the researcher began with an initial 300 allegedly relevant articles but in the end, only 85 were specifically applicable in the study. This meant that there was a lot of time and other resources wasted in reading through the 215 articles that were not used in the dissertation. Another shortcoming is the possibility of the incompleteness of the data in the research. Since this dissertation was on comparisons between the EU and US policies, most of the available data dated back to 2012. Only six (6) articles were done in 2013. Even among these, none had been done after March. Consequently, the researcher had to update most of these research findings as statistics have changed over the past half-year.

The result was a comprehensive presentation of the research design, methodology, process, and results. The researcher’s recommendations, based on various related researches as well as personal analysis after conducting the research form the final part of the dissertation after the conclusion. Concerning policy considerations as far as the United States and the European Union are concerned, it is important to note that both jurisdictions are viewed as unions for this paper. The United States is one nation that comprises of a myriad of states, each with respective state governments. However, the United States Government runs at the federal level to unify all these respective states under unilateral regulations. One of these regulations involves agriculture. On the other hand, the European Union consists of independent states that have come together specifically for economic integration, with the addendum of political and minimum social integration (Baumol, & Oates 1988). Consequently, this lack of foundational congruence during the formation of the European Union is a major factor for consideration when discussing the policy embraced by the EU concerning agriculture.

In conducting this research, several assumptions will be held by the researcher, including that the respective policies, namely the COMMON AGRICULTURAL POLICY for the EU and the Farm Bills for the United States are efficient in their respective existence. This is to say that the researcher presumes that the Farm Bill is a wholesome policy in as far as the intention of the policymakers at the time of its creation is concerned, as is the COMMON AGRICULTURAL POLICY. A second assumption held by the researcher is that whichever of the two policies that have so far yielded optimum results in as far as the achievement of the desired goals intended by the policymakers is superior to the rival regulation. This means that one of the considerations in this dissertation’s application of a measuring gauge to determine the efficiency of the respective agricultural policies is the primary objective outlined by the policymakers during the creation of the policy. However, the researcher will also incorporate the success enjoyed by either union as per the universal principles of agricultural prowess. The latter gauge will be applied by providing a comprehensive view of ideal agricultural conditions and the requisite policies for the establishment of such a condition.

The European Union policy, Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) is similar in many ways to the United States, farm bills. For one, both policies are entrenched and they have amended their clauses to conform to the requirements of the Uruguay Round Agricultural Agreement signed by WTO member states. Secondly, both policies are supportive of market liberalization and move away from state or government intervention tendencies (IATP, 2007). This is a reflection of a willingness to cooperate with the global environment in terms of shifting from the trend of market interference. The idea of the Uruguay Round Agricultural Agreement was to make the agricultural sector as similar as possible to the other industrial sectors. Looking into both the United States Policy and the European Union Policy, both blocs have embraced this idea. Evidence of this cooperation is in the inclination of both the United States and the European Union to eradicate commodity price and income support. This attention has instead been shifted to the alternative non – commodity sectors of rural development, energy production, infrastructural development, conservation and nutrition, food aid, and horticulture among others (Ong’wen, & Wright 2007).

However, there are poignant differences that distinguish the European Union policy from the United States’ policy, and key among these is caused by the nature of the union. The European Union is a union of several member states, which came to birth as the European Economic Commission, EEC under the Treaty of Rome in 1958. At the onset, there were only six members but as of 2012, this membership had reached 35 (Monke 2010). It is noteworthy that each respective country signing up to the European Union does not change her political or legal institutions, but simply signs the charter agreeing to be bound by the European Union’s regulations, in return for the enjoyment of financial and political benefits that come from integration. This is not the case with the United States, which is one nation with many states. It has one president and so any conventions or treaties that are entered into by the president of the United States or any regulations or policies that are made at the congress are binding to all the states (Manor 1999, p. 32). Although each state may come up with policies that are complementary to the federal law, they cannot afford to remove themselves from the federal law, as this would be unconstitutional.

With the European Union, there is a respect for domestic legislations of member states except in cases of extreme non – conformity. In case of non-compliance, the only action that can be taken by the European Union is sanctioning the deviant member (U.S. Farm Bill and the EU Common Agriculture Policy at Crossroads A Global Dialogue on U.S., Canadian, and EU Agriculture policies 2007). With this legal background in mind, it is safe to point out that the nature of the United States’ farm bills is perpetual. In other words, it is an ever-changing bill that is revisited every five or so years to determine the best and most comprehensive way forward concerning the agricultural sector. This is similar to some level, to the CAP of the European Union as that is a law that forms part of the establishing convention of the European Union and thus it is unlikely to change completely and more likely to do so gradually.

However, in the United States, given the political background of the United States, the governmental structure keeps changing each term and the successive administration is free to undo the former administration’s work out of spite and to the detriment of the country’s economy and agricultural sector. An example is the Obama administration, which has since extended the life span of the 2008 farm bill to September 2013 whereas it had been intended to last until June of 2012 (Brandford, Josling, & Bureau 2011, p. 33). In case the Obama administration had not been re-elected, the successive government may have gone either way in light of the current controversies concerning ethanol production and supply. The short term nature of succession is toxic to the development of long-lasting and benefitting legislation and is one of the reasons why the United States’ agricultural sector is lagging behind the European Union’s agricultural sector despite the United States having more arable land and technology to propel agriculture.

The European Union’s CAP has been in place since mid-1900 as the principal course of action in governing the agricultural sector of Western Europe. However, it has attracted a lot of controversies both internally and externally due to its tendency to siphon all the financial reserves of the union thus raising questions on distribution and budgeting. External concerns have been raised due to the tendency of the EU agricultural policy to “protect her domestic markets from overseas competition as well as its tendency to cause overproduction” (Peterson et al. 2009, p. 4). However, the Common Agricultural Policy managed to subsist for more than three decades in its flawed status, and only in 1992 did the reforms on the policy take root. However, the product of the CAP reforms is a stunning specimen that would be unrecognizable to the initiators of the CAP legislation.

The United States’ Farm policies came into being close to eight decades ago as temporary solution providers to the crisis caused by the Great Depression and the Dust Bowl in the 1930s. Consequently, the foundational basis of the US agricultural basis as a price support for commodities that were categorized under ‘program’ crops. This was as opposed to ‘specialty crops’ which did not enjoy the same support from the government. Another form of support was a governmental intervention into the agricultural markets of the day (Public Citisen 2006). These foundational principles of the US agricultural policy are still in existence up to date but for a bit of toning down and refinement. For instance, the price support still exists in part, with the major portion of it having been overthrown by direct payments. Although livestock production had not hitherto suffered excessive state intervention, the policy changes through the years updated this status through tariff reduction. Another change that has contributed to the aforementioned refinement is the abandonment of restrictions in production and state intervention into the agricultural markets (Purgał 2012, p. 23).

In Europe, direct payments were introduced post-1992, specifically in 1994 after the signing of the Uruguay Round Agricultural Agreements that required signatories to withdraw supports and minimize state intervention into the agricultural markets. Another significant factor regarding the CAP is the equitable distribution of direct payments. Whereas the CAP regulations allow individual nations a wide berth for flexibility in determining how they will adjust their systems to direct payments, there still exists a divide in the actual implementation of this policy. Some nations have responded by immediately cutting out the payments to the standards that they can comfortably accommodate such as Denmark whereas others are allowing a transitory adjustment, such as Germany (Richardson, Monke, & Falk 2008, p. 16). Both way, in the end, the payments will reduce in quantity to reflect the capacity of respective member states, and this will have achieved the much-desired equitability in the distribution of direct payments. The past contention was the fact that the standard of payment was uniform across the European Union and this was irrespective of the type of crop (Orden, Blandford, & Josling 2011, p. 67). However, elevating the threshold required to be eligible and making payments in terms of per hectare arrangements fits the bill and is more equitable

With the maturity of the concept of environmental sustainability, the agricultural sector is increasingly being looked into for solutions to correct the damage done and prevent further damage to biodiversity. Among the key policies being addressed on either side of the Atlantic is the introduction of biofuel policies to work in tandem with traditional farm policies. In the United States, Congress has mandated the integration of renewable and fossil fuels. The renewable in question is alcohol, which is formed from corn. To facilitate the implementation of this policy, the government has put in place various incentives, including tax credits and protection of the domestic market from imports to encourage local ethanol production. Whereas this is a noble cause in terms of salvaging the environment, it is still subject to much criticism due to the implication it has on food stocks. Since the corn producers are receiving very attractive subsidies in producing corn for ethanol generation, this is likely to harm food prices (Sachs, Santarius, Murphy, & De La Torre Ugarte 2007). The use of corn for feedstock in ethanol production jeopardizes American consumers’ prices for food and the 2008 Farm Bill does not provide for correctional provisions for this phenomenon. The Bill, which was supposed to be reviewed and updated in June of 2012, was not thus reviewed and debates are still ongoing as to the best way forward after the Obama Administration postponed review for September 2013 (IATP 2009).

In Europe, the applicable biofuel is biodiesel, which is manufactured from extracts of domestic oilseeds such as rapeseeds. Additionally, the European Union has various international tree plantations for the specific production of tree oils such as palm oil. These biofuel promotion projects are also mandatorily incorporated into law to ensure uniform application and just cause. The concern concerning food stocks and prices is less felt in Europe because the vegetable oils that are harnessed domestically are scarcely used by the indigenous population. However, the Maghreb and the Middle East withstand the worst of this shortage in vegetable oils, as the prices are exorbitant in their markets whereas initially the imports were reasonably priced (Thurston 2005).

The EU CAP has a provision known as the ‘Second Pillar’, which provides for the enabling clauses of using biofuels (liquid fuels) and biomass to meet the established standard of 10 percent of the transportation fuel being from renewable sources (U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service 2000, p. 2). A key matter in need of resolution is the method of accountability that should be adopted by the European Union in accounting for ILUC or Indirect Land Use Changes. This is about the determination of what biofuel production is sustainable by the budget. The objective and measuring instrument is the amount of carbon emission that is associated with the production of such fuels.

The EU CAP was last reviewed in 2003. It is currently undergoing a review to change some of the primary provisions to update the CAP to the current global standards. A key issue under review is the budgetary provisions. It is noteworthy that the CAP budget has maintained stability over the past three decades. In 1991, it was 50 billion Euros and in 2007, it was still around the same amount (Wiggerthale 2005). This is interesting especially since there have been (as from 1994), several reviews in terms of policies that have impacted the budgetary allocations such as the shift from price support to direct payments, the reduction of export subsidies, and the changes in a public intervention.

The stability in costs is evidence of a sense of acceptance and success of the CAP policy within the European Union. However, it should not be taken at the surface level because respective policies intrinsic to the CAP policy have changed dramatically. Statistically, direct payments increased from 10 billion Euros to 36 billion Euros in 2008. The market intervention through price supported amounted to a paltry four billion Euros from the 1991 figure of 23 billion Euros. The export subsidies were reduced to one billion Euros from 13 billion Euros and the rural development projects amounted to nine billion Euros from a minimum of five billion Euros in 1991 (Timothy, 2007). Therefore, it is apparent that this stabilization in the budgetary allocations conceals the actual changes that have occurs within the EU policy environment. This could be construed to imply that the initial allocators of the 50 billion Euros as the CAP budget were on track and had an idea of how to go about achieving the policy requirements of CAP. It is one of the stronger arguments, besides the one on CAP acceptability for the success of the EU policy as far as agriculture is concerned.

However, with the present political climate, there is an apparent inclination by the policymakers to make a phenomenal change to the budgetary allocations of the EU that could easily topple the delicate equilibrium that has subsisted for more than three decades. This is in the form of devolution. The current legislators are posting that the respective member states of the European Union contribute towards the budgetary requirements to run national policies. This translates to a reduction in incentives available to support some programs and projects.

The First Pillar (Pillar 1) projects presently receive 100% support from the European Union. This pillar deals with matters of direct payments, subsidies, and price-related incomes (National Academy of Sciences 2009). However, the second pillar, which encompasses the provision of sustainable agricultural practices and services, is to be primarily sponsored by national governments. This section of CAP deals with the production and use of bio-ethanol and other biomasses and biofuels. The reason that has been given for requiring state sponsorship is the fact that the national governments are the implementers of EU policies through the adoption or ratification of agreements passed at the EU level domestically. However, the effect of this arrangement will be the favoring of the programs and projects of the first pillar over those of the second pillar much to the detriment of the environment. Consequently, both the European Union’s CAP and the United States’ Farm Bills need modification concerning the implications of using food stocks as feedstocks for renewable energy production.

A similarity between the European Union and the United States policy is in the regulation of biofuels (USDA 2011). With the European Union, BioFuel regulation does form part of the CAP but at the second pillar level, which is secondary in priority to other agricultural sector concerns. With the US farm bills, the BioFuel regulation is not stipulated outright. Indeed, since the 1985 farm bill environmental sustainability has been of primary importance in the agricultural sector policy regulation. However, specific provisions regulating the specific mechanisms incorporated in the production and distribution of biofuels does not exist in the CAP in its current format. Such information is contained in other environment-related regulations. The same holds for the United States’ farm bills. The 2008 Bill, which is yet to be reviewed and ratified by September 2013, does not contain elaborate biofuels provisions.

This gap in policy formulation concerning the agricultural policy is detrimental in more than one way. First off, it means that the respective states in the case of the US and the respective nations in terms of the EU have room to maneuver and get away with environmentally unsustainable policies (U.S. Farm Bill and the EU Common Agriculture Policy at Crossroads A Global Dialogue on U.S., Canadian and EU Agriculture policies 2007). This is because they have been given the mandate to incorporate sustainability policies for their respective governments but no standard has been established at a federal or bloc level to direct their respective adoptions.

Moreover, whereas previously the environmental policies were the primary regulators of biofuel production in both regions, the contribution of the agricultural sector can no longer be underestimated. The agricultural sector is responsible for the production of corn, which is used in the production of ethanol; it is also responsible for producing oilseeds that are used to produce biodiesel in the European Union (U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service 2001; International Food & Agricultural Trade Policy Council 2011). Additionally, it is responsible for the production of mitigating products that can counter or reverse the mal effects of the GHG emissions already made and that continue to be made into the ecosystem. Consequently, it is becoming apparent that the agricultural sector needs to be a primary decision-maker in the formulation of regulations related to biodiversity.

Consumers throughout the world, but especially in Europe and the United States are becoming more and more product specific. That is to say that they care about how the product came to be. Such concern is expressed in the form of a preference for organic food products or the overt concern about animal welfare (Mullarkey, Cooper, & Skully 2001). They are also concerned about the environmental implications of water usage, air, and soil pollution and so farmers and legislators alike are under a lot of pressure to promote sustainability.

Consequently, in the United States, the nature of debating is shifting especially as concerns the negotiations and discussions between politicians and farmers. Whereas throughout history the main concern lodged by farmers has been the income that is incumbent from their production, of late, this has changed. Now farmers are complaining over the excessive supervision that is being conducted on their techniques and processes by agencies such as the United States Environmental Protection Agency, (EPA) (Wiggerthale 2005). Their cause of disagreement is that such a body is not event party to the implementation or formulation or implementation of agricultural sector policies yet they have strict codes of conduct that farmers are being required to comply with. Such complaints have met a deaf ear from the government because it has indeed become apparent that farmers’ techniques and methods require both supervision and direction from environmental experts. This is because they deal directly with the ecosystem and therein lays any possible avenue for the salvation of the environment, and agriculture’s contribution to the fight against global warming (U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service 2000).

An example of a justification for such strict oversight is the results of recent research conducted on the economic repercussions of the reduction in the population of bees, which play a vital role in pollination and other critical animals such as bats. Seed dispersal is deteriorating due to the near extinction of various critical players in bio diversity. Another crucial factor with regards to considerations for the agricultural policy environments is the climatic changes that are rocking the world. With the melting of the polar ice caps as a clear indication that all is not well in terms of climatic balance, it is necessary to prepare for all eventualities. The best way to guarantee preparation would be through the enactment of relevant and adequate agricultural policy. With this in mind, recent environmental policies have incorporated agricultural procedures and techniques in various provisions to reduce GHG emissions and mitigate any other sources’ emissions via agricultural sustainability.

Although such measures are still at their budding stages, it is apparent that they will be instrumental in protecting the environment while simultaneously ensuring the running of sustainable agricultural programs throughout the bloc. Such measures would assist in the contribution that the agricultural sector is customized to make in the war against global warming. They would also assist in the overthrowing of the fossil fuels monopoly by instituting renewable fuels as a viable alternative. This would be in appreciation of the worth of yield and woodland as carbon elements. The political environment of agricultural policies is influenced by the global prices of commodities. Over the past three decades, the trend has been negative concerning availing incentives for political reform geared towards better agricultural support. However, with the strong demands hailing from emerging countries and the deceleration of the growth of production by developing countries, it is possible that shortly, the political arena throughout the globe will be fertile for the formulation of productive policies. Additionally, most of the farmers that had initially signed up their lands as working lands in the United States program that works on reforestation and restoration into grasslands and wetlands of sections that were formerly agricultural lands are looking to withdraw from these contracts.

This is because of the lucrative subsidies and other incentives that have been offered up by the government to encourage the production of ethanol from corn as a renewable fuel. More pressure is expected from this group of farmers especially if it is determined that ethanol can be produced from cellulosic by-products (IATP 2009; Ferrer, & Kaditi 2010). This is because in such a case, the farmers will require their marginal lands to promote such products. Other factors that affect the policy environment concerning agriculture include price hikes, such as those experienced between 2007 and 2008 as well as in 2012. These acted as a wake-up call and caused alarm over food security throughout the globe. In return, various policies have been considered and are ready for enactment to protect against possible results that are less favorable for policy development.

Parastatals encourage self-reliance and simultaneously ensure government checking. To elaborate that point, in the absence of such parastatals, the government is free to monopolize the agricultural sector by either restricting the production of particular products or by requiring the production of the same. Since the government is in power, there is nothing to hinder it from passing regulations to control the production of various crops or livestock. The policies governing the agricultural sectors in both the European Union and the United States have both similarities and differences. Fundamentally, the policies are similar in that both are aligned towards the abolishment of market intervention by the state or the EU regime. However, the means through which this end is achieved vary across the Atlantic. In the United States, price support still exists to a certain level although the government is working towards eliminating it, while in the European Union; price support has been completely eradicated except for specific commodities, especially in dairy production.

Secondly, the CAP is more elaborate than the US farm bills in terms of making provisions for specific regulation of sub-sectors. The biofuel policies are a manifestation of this distinction as the European Union comes off as being better organized in the production of its bio fuels. Evidence of this phenomenon is found in the fact that Europe’s inhabitants are not suffering any food shortages due to the harnessing of vegetable oils for biodiesel and external parties such as the Maghreb and the Middle East feel the effect. On the other hand, in the United States, corn production has become controversial, as there lacks an elaborate policy on how to separate food stocks from feedstocks (Bureau, & Louis-Pascal 2009). Consequently, food prices are shooting up as farmer priorities based on renewable energy incentives such as tax credits are shifting to feedstock production. This is s noble cause concerning sustainability but the folly is in the lack of regulatory measures to ensure food security.

As noted in various segments of this paper, the agricultural sectors in the United States and the European Union are inherently different and they have unique malfunctioning points (Ferrer, & Kaditi 2010). Consequently, the recommendations proffered will be in the form of respective blocs, first the European Union, then the United States. The European Union’s agricultural sector is currently suffering from budgetary costs, as is the United States’ agricultural sector. However, both have differing causes for this malfunctioning and so both require different treatments.

References

Ackrill, R & Kay, A 2004, CAP reform, path dependence and the EU budget, presentation to the Agricultural Economics Society Annual Conference, Imperial College, London.

American Farmland Trust 2002, The Farmland Protection Toolbox: Fact Sheet,1998, Web.

Banse, M, Van Meijl, H, Tabeau, A & Woltjer, G 2008, ‘Will EU Biofuel Policies affect Global Agricultural Markets?’, European Review of Agricultural Economics, vol. 35 no. 2, pp. 117-141.

Barnard, G, Whittaker, D, Westenbarger, H & Ahearn, M 1997, ‘Evidence of Capitalisation of Direct Government Payments into U.S. Cropland Values’, American Journal of Agricultural Economics, vol. 79 no. 5, pp.1642-1650.

Baumol, W & Oates, W 1988, The Theory of Environmental Policy, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

Bebbington, A, Merrill-Sands, D & Farrington, J 1994, Farmer and Community Organisations in Agricultural Research and Extension: Functions, Impacts and Questions AgREN Network Paper 47, Overseas Development Institute, London.

Bernstein, J, Cooper, J & Claassen, R 2011, ‘Agriculture and the Environment In the United States and EU’, U.S.-EU Food and Agriculture Comparisons / WRS-04-04, vol. 1 no. 1, pp. 66-78.

Blandford, D & Orden, D 2011, United States Chapter 4. In D. B. Orden David, WTO Disciplines on Agricultural Support: Seeking a Fair Basis for Trade, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge UK.

Blandford, D & Josling, T 2011, The WTO Agricultural Modalities Proposals and their Impact on Domestic Support in the EU and the US, World Bank, Washington, D.C.

Brandford, D, Josling, T & Bureau, J 2011, Farm policy in the US and EU: The Current Status and the Way Ahead, International Food and Agricultural Trade Policy Council, Washington DC.

Bureau, J & Louis-Pascal, M 2009, CAP reform beyond 2013: An idea for a longer view, Burmingham, Notre Europe.

Caldwell, M 2004, European Model of Agriculture, Oxford University Press, Oxford.

Commission of the European Communities (CEC) 1991, The Development and Future of the CAP. COM 91 (100), Office for Official Publications of the European Communities, Luxembourg.

Dennis, O 2007, Sustainable biomass land reserves for a sustainable future, Web.

DFID 2004, Effective policy and public expenditure reform for pro-poor agricultural development, Working paper for the Renewable Natural Resources and Agriculture Team, DFID Policy Division, Oxford Policy Management, Oxford.

Dorward, A, Fan, S, Kydd, J, Lofgren, H, Morrison, J, Poulton, C, Rao, N, Smith, L, Tchale, H, Thorat, S, Urey, I & Wobst, P 2004, Institutions and policies for pro-poor agricultural growth, Overseas Development Institute, London.

Duffy, P, Taylor, R, Cain, D & Young, J 1994, ‘The Economic Value of Farm Program Base’, Land Economics, vol. 70 no. 1, pp. 318-329.

Ellis, F & Biggs, S 2001, ‘Evolving themes in rural development 1950s-2000s’, Development Policy Review, vol. 19 no. 4, pp. 437-448.

European Commision 2011, Communication from the Commission to the European Parliament, The Council, The Economic and Social Committee, and the Committee of the Regions,: A Budget for 2020, COM(2011) 500 final, European Commission, Brussels.

European Commission 2010, The CAP towards 2020: Meeting the food, natural resources and territorial challenges of the future, COM(2010)672, European Commission, Brussels.

Fan, S & Rao, N 2003, Public Spending in Developing countries: trends, determination, and impact, Environment and Production Technology Division Discussion Paper No. 99, International Food Policy Research Institute, Washington.

Ferrer, J & Kaditi, E 2010, The EU added value of agricultural expenditure – from market to multifunctionality – gathering criticism and success stories of the CAP, Centre for European Policy Studies for the European Parliament, Brussels.

Grindle, M & Thomas, J 1991, Public Choices and Policy Change, Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore.

Heather, S & Muller, M 2006, Staying home, how ethanol will change U.S. Corn exports, Web.

Heniff, B 2010, Budget Enforcement Procedures: Senate Pay-As-You-Go (PAYGO) Rule, Congressional Research Service, R31943, Washington, DC.

IATP 2007, IATP trade and global governance department, The guessing game, how will the U.S.play agriculture trade in 2007? February 2007, Web.

IATP 2007, IATP, A Fair Farm Bill for Conservation, Web.

IATP 2009, Sustainable Agriculture Coalition, Promoting Sustainable Cellulosic Bioenergy Crops With the Conservation Security Program, Web.

International Food & Agricultural Trade Policy Council 2011, Economic Partnership Agreements (EPAs) and African regional integration: Have negotiations helped or hindered regional integration?, IPC Discussion Paper, Washington, DC.

Jean-Christophe, B & Witzke, H 2010, The Single Payment Scheme after 20123: New Approach – New Targets, Study conducted for the European Parliament, Directorate General for Internal Policies, Cambridge.

Josling, T 2008, EU15 and EFTA, Distortions to Agricultural Incentives: A Global Perspective, Palgrave Macmillan, Washington DC.

Keeney, D & Muller, M 2006, Water use by ethanol plants: potential challenges, Web.

Koning, N 2006, , Web.

Krissoff, B, Ballenger, N, Dunmore, J & Gray, D 1996, Exploring Linkages Among Agriculture, Trade, and the Environment: Issues for the Next Century, Economic Research Service, U.S. Department of Agriculture AER No. 738, Chicago.

Krueger, A 1990, ‘Government failures in development’, Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 4 no. 3, pp. 9-23.

Kydd, J & Dorward, A 2001, The Washington Consensus on poor country agriculture: analysis, prescription and institutional gaps, Overseas Development Institute, London.

Lipton, M 2005, From policy aims and small-farm characteristics to farm science needs, The Research Workshop, Wye.

Long-Sutehall, T, Sque, M & Addington-Hall, J 2010, ‘Secondary analysis of qualitative data: a valuable method for exploring sensitive issues with an elusive population?’, Journal of Research in Nursing , vol. 16 no. 4, pp. 335–344.

Manor, J 1999, The Political Economy of Democratic Decentralisation, World Bank, Washington DC.

Marita, W 2005, What’s wrong with EU agriculture subsidies, Web.

Mills, M, Van de Bunt, G & de Bruijn, J 2006, ‘Comparative Research: Persistent Problems and Promising Solutions’, Journal of International Sociology , vol. 21 no. 5, pp. 619–631.

Monke, J 2010, Previewing the Next Farm Bill Unfunded and Early Expiring Provisions, Web.

Mullarkey, D, Cooper, J & Skully, D 2001, Multifunctionality of Agriculture: Do Mixed Goals Distort Trade, Choices, World Bank, Washington DC.

National Academy of Sciences 2009, Liquid Transportation Fuels from Coal and Biomass: Technological Status, Costs, Environmental Impacts, Washington, DC, World Bank.

OECD 2012, Economic Accounts for Agriculture 2009, Web.

Ong’wen, O & Wright, S 2007, Small Farmers and the Future of Sustainable Agriculture, Web.

Orden, D, Blandford, D & Josling, T 2011, WTO Disciplines on Agricultural Support: Seeking a Fair Basis for Trade, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.

Peterson et al. 2009, ‘Environmental policies for a multifunctional agricultural sector in open economies’, European Review of Agricultural Economics, vol. 29 no. 4, p. 4.

Potter, C 1998, Against the Grain: Agri-Environmental Reform in the United States and the European Union, CAB International, Oxford.

Public Citizen 2006, Ten Year Track Record of the North American Free Trade Agreement U.S. Farmers and Agriculture, Web.

Purgał, P 2012, Reform Of The Of The Common Agricultural Policy – Theoretical And Practical Aspects, CAB International, Oxford.

Reichert, T 2006, A closer look at EU agricultural subsidies, Web.

Richardson, J 2005, CRS Report RL33690: Food Stamps and Nutrition Programs in the 2002 Farm Bill, Congressional Researc Service, Washingtone DC.

Richardson, J, Monke, J & Falk, G 2008, CRS Report R41374, Reducing SNAP (Food Stamp) Benefits Provided by the ARRA: P.L. 111-226 and P.L. 111-296, Congressional Resarch Service, Washington DC.

Sachs, W, Santarius, T, Murphy, S & De La Torre Ugarte, D 2007, World Trade and the Regeneration of Agriculture, Web.

Schnepf, R & Hanrahan, C 2011, U.S. and EU Agricultural Support: Overview and Comparison, Congressional Research Service, Washington, DC.

Schoonover, H & Muller, M 2006, (IATP). Food without thought, how U.S. farm policy contributes to obesity, Web.

Shields, D, Monke, J & Schepf, R 2010, Farm Safety Net Programs: Issues for the Next Farm Bill, Congressional Research Service, Report for Congress, R41317, Washington, DC.

Swinbank, A & Josling,T 2012, EU Agricultural Policies and European Integration: A Thematic Review of the Literature, Palgrave Macmillan, Houndmills.

Tancu, M 2010, US’ and EU’s Agricultural Policies in the Context of GATT/WTO, Aarhus University Centre of International Business Law Department of Business Law, Berlin.

Tangermann, S 2011, Direct Payments in the CAP Post 2013, DG Internal Policies, European Parliament, IP/B/AGRI/IC/2011-003, Cambridge.

Thurston, J 2005, Why Europe deserves a better agriculture policy, Web.

Timothy, A 2007, Wise and Elanor Starmer, Industrial Livestock Companies’ Gains from Low Feed Prices, 1997-2005 GDAE Policy Brief, Web.

U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service 2000, ‘Small and Large Farms Both Growing in Number’, Rural Conditions and Trends, vol. 10 no. 2, p. 2.

U.S. Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service 2001, U.S. Agricultural Trade Update. FAU-59, Charles Sumner School, Washington D.C.

U.S. Farm Bill and the EU Common Agriculture Policy at Crossroads 2007, A Global Dialogue on U.S., Canadian and EU Agriculture policies, Charles Sumner School, Washington D.C.

USDA 2011, Media Briefing: Remarks by Agriculture Secretary Vilsack on President’s Proposed FY 2012 Budget, Office of Communications, Washington, DC.

Yano, Y, Blandford, D & Surry, Y 2011, Do Current U.S. Ethanol Policies Make Sense? Policy Issues PI10, Agricultural and Applied Economics Association, Web.

More related papers Related Essay Examples
Cite This paper
You're welcome to use this sample in your assignment. Be sure to cite it correctly

Reference

IvyPanda. (2021, February 25). Agricultural Policies in the EU vs. the US. https://ivypanda.com/essays/agricultural-policies-in-the-eu-vs-the-us/

Work Cited

"Agricultural Policies in the EU vs. the US." IvyPanda, 25 Feb. 2021, ivypanda.com/essays/agricultural-policies-in-the-eu-vs-the-us/.

References

IvyPanda. (2021) 'Agricultural Policies in the EU vs. the US'. 25 February.

References

IvyPanda. 2021. "Agricultural Policies in the EU vs. the US." February 25, 2021. https://ivypanda.com/essays/agricultural-policies-in-the-eu-vs-the-us/.

1. IvyPanda. "Agricultural Policies in the EU vs. the US." February 25, 2021. https://ivypanda.com/essays/agricultural-policies-in-the-eu-vs-the-us/.


Bibliography


IvyPanda. "Agricultural Policies in the EU vs. the US." February 25, 2021. https://ivypanda.com/essays/agricultural-policies-in-the-eu-vs-the-us/.

If, for any reason, you believe that this content should not be published on our website, please request its removal.
Updated:
This academic paper example has been carefully picked, checked and refined by our editorial team.
No AI was involved: only quilified experts contributed.
You are free to use it for the following purposes:
  • To find inspiration for your paper and overcome writer’s block
  • As a source of information (ensure proper referencing)
  • As a template for you assignment
1 / 1