Paper Recycling: Environmental and Business Issues Dissertation

Exclusively available on IvyPanda Available only on IvyPanda
Updated: Apr 21st, 2024

Saving the Environment

Almost everything can be recycled. From paper to vehicles we ride in can be recycled. Recycling is the most effective way to reduce the amount of waste. It prevents useful materials from being landfilled or burned. By preserving waste disposal it cuts pollution and conserves energy and natural resources. Recycled aluminium instead of aluminium ore cuts air pollutions by 95 percent, water pollution by 97 percent, and energy use by 95 percent.

We will write a custom essay on your topic a custom Dissertation on Paper Recycling: Environmental and Business Issues
808 writers online

Substituting scrap steel for virgin materials cuts 85 percent of pollution, water pollution by 76 percent, 63 percent of energy use and 40 percent of water use. Making paper from recycled materials cuts 74 percent of pollution, 35 percent of water pollution, 70 percent energy use and 58 percent of water use. Recycling is cost effective, especially since it avoids costs of disposal. (Engel, 1997, p-32)

Recycling paper produces less toxic waste than making paper from wood pulp. It requires fewer chemicals and less bleaching. Waste paper must be de-inked which then ends up in a sludge that has ink, clay, fibre fragments and other materials. The sludge is sometimes buried in hazardous waste landfills but it is non-toxic and can be used as a soil conditioner. People in the United States use 25 percent of all paper since 2002 but this has increased since the increase in collection.

There are several types of paper when recycled. In order for paper to be properly recycled, the several types of paper must be separated because the different types of paper must be used for different types of products. One category is newspapers. This is the most common paper to recycle because it is the main kind of paper collected from homes. Recycled newsprint makes newsprint and paperboard, such as food boxes with the grey inside. Another group of paper is the high-grade paper this is the white typing and writing paper, index cards and computer printouts.

This is used to make printing, writing and tissue paper. The third major group of paper is corrugated cardboard and other paperboard. This is the largest source of waste paper. In 1999, 50 percent of this group was recovered by recycling in the United States. (Burton, 2003) Businesses that use a lot of paperboard usually have their own baling equipment to prepare for the paper mills. Their paper is recycled to make all sorts of paperboard. Other papers such as envelopes, blue print papers, coloured papers and others must be recycled separately because they contain contaminants like glues and dyes.

Good Business

Today the recycling of paper is a good business. By developing a transactional e-commerce website to sell, purchase and exchange used and new paper to a broad audience. An organization that will expect to turn out to be an entirely Internet based organization with no genuine substantial infrastructure or big shop. By working online, Radiant Inc. aims to offer used and new paper products of the uppermost quality to all its consumers and in the procedure augment Radiant Inc. size through an increased consumer base and superior profits. By working online, paper recycling based organizations will also aspire to turn out to be market leader in the area and ultimately the United States. (Howell, 2003) These organizations can make good money by focusing on the following points:

  • To broaden their consumer base on a supplementary national level
  • To amplify market position to turn out to be one of the leading players in the industry
  • To make profits through increased sales, purchases and exchanges of new and used paper products.

Through the website, one can get the old paper products from all over the area in replacement of new paper products. Since all the people used to throw their paper wastes to the dustbins that are later gathered by the local government and afterwards these are sold to paper recycling firms. So when people will know they can get few useful objects by giving useless paper wastes like old book, newspaper and magazines and publicity material of different. They will keep the paper waste according to your requirements and will also be willing to drop the waste to your place. (Short, 2004, p-1217) Through the website, people can inform you about the quantity of wastes available at their place that can be picked.

1 hour!
The minimum time our certified writers need to deliver a 100% original paper

Works Cited

Burton, Bob. Nuclear Power, Pollution and Politics. London: Rutledge, 2003.

Engel, Cynthia. “Taking Note of the Paper Industry.” Monthly Labour Review 120.9 (1997): 32+.

Howell, David R., Richard Silberglitt, and Douglas Norland. Industrial Materials for the Future R&D Strategies: A Case Study of Boiler Materials for the Pulp and Paper Industry /. Santa Monica, CA: Rand, 2003.

Short, Megan. “Taking Back the Trash: Comparing European Extended Producer Responsibility and Take-Back Liability to U.S. Environmental Policy and Attitudes.” Vanderbilt Journal of Translational Law 37.4 (2004): 1217+.

Appendices

Taking note of the paper industry by Cynthia Engel

Consumer participation in recycling, improvements in technology, increased consumption of paper products, and liberalization of international trade together have had an enormous influence on employment on paper-related industries

Paper is an indispensable component in the production, packaging and delivery of a wide variety of products used daily by most Americans. For many it begins with breakfast. Most of us would be lost without our newspaper, coffee filters, napkins, cereal boxes, and milk and juice cartons. In some cases, our entire breakfast is baked, sold, reheated, and served in its original paperboard box.

Americans consume more paper than do the citizens of most countries. Compared with the 1994 world average of 97 pounds, the U.S. per capita consumption of paper is more than 700 pounds, approximately 2 pounds per person per day. Per capita consumption of paper products in the United States has grown 43 percent since 1980.(1)

Steady increases in paper consumption have had divergent impacts on employment in manufacturing production, in wholesale trade distribution, and in recycling collection. Employment in paper manufacturing, which historically has been volatile, has fluctuated less in recent years. Employment gains have been elusive, however, and 16,000 jobs have been lost, on net, since 1990. (2) At the same time, employment in recycling collection and paper distribution reflects a steady and increasing rate of growth. Increases in these jobs in recent history have far outweighed employment declines in paper manufacturing.

Employment is driven in part by changing regulations and consumer demands. New government regulations and an environmentally conscious population have required industry to use more recycled waste and to produce fewer contaminants in production. These changes have led to costly, but necessary, investments in new equipment. Improvements have been implemented with state-of-the-art technology, resulting in less labour-intensive employment. While increased productivity within paper manufacturing has allowed output to grow even in times when employment has not, recycling and exports have buoyed employment in the paper-related industries.

This article examines the changing market for paper, including the demand for recycled products and exports, and its effect on employment trends.

Types of paper

Paper manufacturers produce both paper and paperboard products. The designation “paper industry” generally refers to the production of both products. Paperboard is used to make items for the packaging of products, such as cardboard boxes, shipping containers for produce, and appliance containers. “Paper” may also identify the subgroup of products that excludes paperboard, such as newspaper, catalogue paper, bond paper, tissue paper, and computer paper. In this article, the term will be used to identify the broader group, including both paper and paperboard products.
Paper products are classified according to content. Products with recycled content contain various amounts of recycled paper, with the balance made up of mill scraps, which often include virgin fibre. Other paper products contain only virgin fibre. To extract the cellulose, which makes up less than half of wood fibre, (3) lignin and other substances are removed. The remaining cellulose is then bleached, beaten, and rinsed, resulting in a pulp to be used for papermaking.

Recycling plants must purchase wastepaper rather than wood, repulp the fibre, and feed the pulp into an ink removal system. At this point, both virgin and recovered pulp go through the same processes.(4) The labour requirements for producing recycled fibre are similar to those for producing virgin fibre, although total costs of recycling are approximately 20 percent less.(5) Production using recycled paper takes less energy than production using virgin paper.(6)

The profitability of recycled products has caused some companies to replace pulp mills with deinking plants and to expand their use of recovered paper in existing mills. Companies are increasing domestic recycling capacity, as worldwide demand for recovered paper is expected to rise to 150 million tons by the year 2000, up from 110 million tons in 1993.(7)
Where the jobs are Paper-related employment is scattered among several industry categories.

he largest block of workers is involved in the manufacture of paper and allied products, (8) which employs 681,000, down slightly from its peak employment of 697,000 in 1990. The second-largest category of paper-related employment is in the paper and paper products component of wholesale trade, where 259,000 are employed in the distribution of paper products. Not included in the 259,000 are another 130,000 jobs in recycling activities undertaken by scrap material brokers and dealers, also found in wholesale trade. While a significant portion of these jobs are directly tied to paper recycling, others support metal or other material recycling.

Scrap material brokers contract with those who actually collect wastepaper, these companies are primarily found in the refuse component of sanitary services (some portion of 156,000 jobs). This list does not exhaust all the remaining jobs that are hidden among the various categories of the Standard Industrial Classification structure: those employed in government transportation services, and those who produce the new equipment, chemicals, and processes to be used in the mills. However, when adding up an abbreviated list of categories, we find well over 1 million jobs supporting the consumption and production of paper in the United States.

Employment trends vary widely

Paper manufacturing. Employment has exhibited significant volatility in paper manufacturing over the last 20 years, with less fluctuation occurring recently. The growth in global markets, combined with production processes that require less human intervention, have contributed to greater stability in employment. Furthermore, the growth of exports has diversified the customer base of paper manufacturers.
As the following tabulation shows, recession-related reductions in the monthly industrial production index and employment in paper manufacturing reveal that recessions have become far less austere over the last two decades:

Percent change in Industrial

Recession production Employment

1973-75 -24 -12

1980 -6 -4

Remember! This is just a sample
You can get your custom paper by one of our expert writers

1981-82 -9 -6

1990-91 2 -2

In the 1973-75 recession, the industrial production index for paper dropped by 24 percent as employment dropped 12 percent, with employment losses regained by 1978. Subsequent recessions do not come close to the severity of this decline. Over the combined recessionary period in the early 1980s, production dropped by 8 percent, while employment fell by 7 percent. Employment recovered much more slowly than in the 1975 recession, taking twice as long to reach percussion levels. In the 1990-91 recessions, the production index increased, as export tonnage grew by 8 percent and employment fell by 2 percent. Fortunately, exports bolstered demand for producers, providing some protection from more dramatic losses.

Although production continues to follow the cyclical pattern of the economy, its vulnerability to domestic recession has been greatly reduced, and with this reduced vulnerability, employment has stabilized. (The declining nature of employment losses during recessions is shown in table 1.) Furthermore, as increasing amounts of capital are substituted for labour, employment declines in the current climate are not associated with reductions in demand.

Recession peaks and troughs in employment in paper.

Recession peaks and troughs in employment in paper.

Recession peaks and troughs in employment in paper.

Recession peaks and troughs in employment in paper.

Recession peaks and troughs in employment in paper.

NOTE: Data are based on monthly, seasonally adjusted employment estimates, except in the cases of pulp mills and scrap material, in which employment does not display measurable seasonality. The peak and trough months used in this table are those specific to the paper manufacturing industry but related to official recessions.
Dash indicates data not available.While recessionary job losses occurred in paper and pulp mills, they were small compared with secular losses posted between 1990 and 1996. Postrecession losses did not reflect a reduction in demand; rather, they reflected technological improvements in the papermaking operation. Between the prerecession peak in 1990 and December of 1996, production increased by 12.6 percent, while employment declined by 1 percent. As computerization became more integral to production operations, mills became more capital-intensive and used less labour.While manufacturing employment is declining overall, exports are adding jobs in paperboard containers and boxes, as exports of paperboard increased dramatically between 1990 and 1996. Employment also is increasing in wholesale trade and in sanitary services, outweighing losses in paper manufacturing. Employment trends in paper manufacturing have been more affected than those in other paper-related industries by changes in production methods and technology. In the other industries, jobs have increased steadily due to increases in recyclable consumption and in demand for paper products at retail outlets.

Paper-related wholesale trade. Unlike those in paper manufacturing, job levels in paper distribution have followed a relatively steady growth pattern. Employment in this category rose by 136 percent between 1972 and 1996, averaging annual growth of 6 percent. (See chart 1.) Since the last recession, employment grew by 9 percent in paper distribution, compared with 8 percent in wholesale trade, and 21,000 jobs were added between 1991 and 1996. Most of the growth occurred in the subcomponent, stationery and office supplies, which distributes computer paper, envelopes, business forms, and related supplies to an increasingly dispersed population.

Reflecting increased demand for recycled paper are jobs within the scrap materials subcomponent of wholesale trade.(9) Employment by establishments categorized under scrap and waste materials increased by 11 percent in 1995 as wastepaper prices soared, and maintained this gain in the weaker paper market of 1996. Between 1991 and 1996, employment rose a moderate 20 percent. (See chart 2.)

Sanitary services. Companies involved in the actual collection of scrap materials fall within the sanitary services industry. As recovery of recyclable materials has grown, so has employment in privately owned sanitary services collection. (Data are not available on employment in government-owned sanitary services, nor are specific data available on private sanitary service workers who are involved in paper recovery.) Employment growth was extremely rapid in the mid-80s, just as use of recycled paper became popular and was deemed a revenue-builder. Another growth spurt occurred between 1993 and 1995, when collection efforts were intensifying. The number of material recovery facilities (MRF) increased from 104 in 1991 to 386 in 1995.(10) Thirty-seven new projects are being planned for 1996-98, although they are smaller in size.(11) Because recycling facilities handle a variety of recyclable materials, the employment impact of paper recycling, as opposed to metal or plastic recycling, is unknown.

While material recovery facilities originally were concentrated in the Northeast, increasing paper demands have resulted in a nearly even distribution of these processing centers throughout the country.(12) Consequently, hiring is no logger restricted to urban environments. Municipal governments throughout the country are experiencing increased demands for haulers and sorters, especially as public ownership of processing facilities has increased since 1995.(13) Networks to collect, sort, and resell paper are continuing to expand.

Factors behind employment trends

As we have seen, employment growth in paper manufacturing is cyclical, and has failed to return to previous peaks during recent recoveries. In contrast, the numbers of jobs in the other paper-related industries have grown in recent years. This section explores some factors behind these differing trends–the increasing demand for paper products in general, and for those with recycled content in particular, and productivity gains from new equipment installed, in part, to use wastepaper instead of wood and to meet new environmental standards.

Changes in domestic demand for paper are primarily tied to changes in population and income growth. Increases in U.S. population and income were particularly strong between 1940 and 1970, followed by growth that was more subdued. While real economic growth has slowed, the information industry has transformed both our home and work lives, also stimulating greater per capita consumption of paper.

Growth in per capita consumption of paper has been averaging 2 percent a year over the last decade, with reductions in consumption coinciding with recessionary periods. (See chart 3.) Per capita consumption hit its peak in 1994, at 734.5 pounds, nearly 100 pounds more than in 1985. Consumption fell in 1995 and through 1996, as higher paper prices encouraged more efficient use. Between 1966 and 1996, consumption of paper (excluding paperboard) almost doubled.(14)

Growth linked to computers. Contrary to speculation that computers would transform the American workplace into a paperless environment, the opposite result has occurred. The increased availability of photocopiers, fax machines, and computers has resulted in a dramatic increase in the use of “office paper” over the last two decades. (See chart 4.) While the U.S. population grew 16 percent from 1972 to 1987, copier paper waste increased by 150 percent and other office paper waste by 87 percent.(15) This growing use is correlated with tremendous growth in production output of printing and writing paper, the type of paper that is used in printers and fax machines. Since 1982, production of printing and writing paper has increased by 60 percent. While the use of electronic mail has displaced some paper usage, conventional wisdom among paper industry forecasters is that “for every ton of paper displaced by computers, there is more than one ton of new demand generated.”(16)

Newspaper and book sales. While much of the growth in paper consumption is generated in the business sector, such as in direct-mail advertising, households also are large consumes, and many products are used by both home and office. Newspapers are a large consumption item for both, accounting for about 25 percent of all paper consumed in the United States (excluding paperboard).(17) Despite the growing popularity of the Internet, 1995 readership of daily newspapers outpaced levels recorded in the 1989-94 period, following a period of decline between 1970 and 1989.(18) The percent of American adults reading a Sunday newspaper also posted a record high in 1995, compared with the 1970-94 period. Clearly, newspapers are a popular medium, and newspaper advertising is more popular than any other form of advertising. Newspapers received 22.4 percent of all advertising dollars in 1995–more than broadcast TV and direct mail, with print-related advertising dominating over other media.(19)

Not only is newspaper circulation healthy, but book sales also are holding their own. Adults purchased 1 billion books in 1995, compared with 776 million in 1991, with most of the increase occurring between 1991 and 1994.(20) While most Americans report reading less, book sales have continued to grow. The Internet may be a substitute for some printed media, but its use also has encouraged sales, with books representing the commodity most frequently sold on the web after computer software. Not surprisingly, computer-related books are an increasing share of total sales, accounting for an additional 13 million books sold between 1991 and 1995.(21)

Furthermore, an increasing standard of living is associated with greater paper usage, as consumption of most products involves some paper content in packaging, labeling, and advertising. Increased consumption is not limited to our borders; as economies develop abroad, worldwide consumption of paper has increased.

A growing foreign market. The market for paper is growing throughout the world, causing U.S. paper exports to more than double between 1985 and 1996.(22) Growth in exports of recovered paper and printing and writing papers has been especially healthy.(23) Exports, in dollars, rose from 6 billion in 1991 to 10 billion in 1996, as tonnage increased by 45 percent. (See table 2.) This burgeoning demand has insulated paper industry workers from further layoffs.

Percent distribution of paper and paperboard exports.
Table 2. Percent distribution of paper and paperboard exports.
Much of U.S. trade is with our partners in the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA); 39 to 45 percent of our exports are sent to Canada and Mexico.(24) In 1994, the first full year after implementation of NAFTA, U.S. paper exports to those two countries increased by a combined 15.5 percent, on a tonnage basis. Exports to Mexico increased 33 percent between 1993 and 1996, and those to Canada by 50 percent.(25) However, despite this rapid growth, the share of all paper exports sent to our NAFTA partners has remained relatively stable due to increased demand from other trading partners. Exports to the emerging market–which are among the fastest growing economies–more than doubled between 1991 and 1996, and represented 8.4 percent of the total market for U.S. producers in 1996, nearly equal to paper exports to Japan. (See table 3.)
Exports of paperboard.
Table 3. Exports of paperboard.
Exports that are correlated with economic growth abroad have stimulated expansion of the U.S. paper industry. More than 50 percent of the industry s growth between 1989 and 1995 was due to this factor.(26) Between 1990 and 1996, an average 11 percent of production was devoted to exports, compared with 6 percent in 1985. According to the American Forest and Paper Association, about 16 percent of total U.S. production went overseas in 1995, and approximately 42 percent of new capacity in the industry made products for export markets.(27) Growth in exports has increased profits significantly for producers in the last couple of years, allowing them to pay down debt on extensive capital investments made in the late 80s and early 90s. New trade agreements are expected to further increase exports to other countries over the next decade.(28)

The factors explored thus far have addressed the demand for all types of paper products. However, undercurrents of a very different type also resulted in profound changes in the industry over last few decades: the demand that paper products be made, at least in part, with recycled materials was growing at the same time that the supply of wastepaper was exploding. Further, there became available new technology that reduced the cost of manufacturing from wastepaper below the cost of a wood-based process for many products. These developments set the stage for job growth in the collection and brokerage of wastepaper.

Recycling–a grassroots movement. Support for recycling arose from citizens’ firm refusals to increase landfill space to contain waste. Environmentalists and waste managers recognized that the major source of landfill waste was paper products,(29) and pressured industry and government to support recycling. While industry had recognized recycled paper as a market niche, increasing demands by the public, coupled with the prospect of greater profits, ensured expansion of this new market.

As technology within paper plants was being replaced to meet cleaner air requirements, the quality of recycled paper products also was being improved, contributing to consumer acceptance of recycled goods. Manufacturers developed processes to incorporate more recycled content in paper while retaining its quality, almost doubling their use of recovered paper between 1985 and 1995.(30) Perhaps unnoticed by end-users, consumption of recycled products has soared. Use of recycled paperboard(31) is a prime example, baying grown 40 percent since 1990 and accounting for 13 percent of paperboard consumption in 1995. Consumption of recycled products also has increased through private sector initiatives and alliances with nonprofit groups.(32) Government agencies are expanding their consumption of recycled products as well.

At every level of government, initiatives have increased the purchase of recycled paper. In 1986, only 13 States and few local governments bad any “buy-recycled” policy. Currently, all 50 States, the District of Columbia, and more than 200 local governments have recycling initiatives in place. Most common are general policies favoring recycled products, set-asides or goals, or a stated price preference for recycled products. There are a few “recycled-only” programs.(33) At the Federal level, the President signed an executive order in 1993 requiring agencies to use recycled products, although minimum requirements on recycled content have been eased for some products. This directed consumption will continue to fuel more invesments in research and development to further increase the quality of recycled products.

A larger, more reliable supply of materials also encourages manufacturers to incorporate recycled paper in production. While manufacturers routinely recycle waste from papermaking processes, consumers are more involved in supplying waste paper, driving the affordability of recycling systems. The incidence of paper recovery is rising, with an all-time high of 44.8 percent collected in 1996 and expectations of increasing recovery rates in the future.(34) According to an annual BioCycle survey,(35) the number of curbside recycling programs increased from about 1,000 in 1988 to 7,265 in 1994, serving about 41 percent of the population in the latter year.

New Equipment and productivity. The growth in the demand for paper has led to large gains in output and has prevented steep job losses in manufacturing following the introduction of less labour-intensive equipment. Expenditures on new plant and equipment by establishments involved in the manufacture of paper products peaked in 1990 and remain higher than expenditures in the 1980s, as capital improvements have increased over the last decade. (See table 4.) Measured in real terms, average dollar expenditures for new capital in the period 1989-94 also are slightly higher than in the prior 5-year period, with 1989 and 1990 standing out as the strongest years for new investments. Although the number of machines installed or rebuilt has been declining since 1988, there has been new growth in recycling equipment.(36)

Because recycling mills can be installed on a smaller scale and at a lower capital cost per ton of output than can virgin pulp mills, these facilities could better support incremental expansions in the industry, especially following a period of capital stock replenishment.(37) Demands for a cleaner environment also have contributed to more rapid replacement of equipment in the industry, likely improving productive efficiency.

Paper manufacturing machines installed or rebuilt as a percent of 1995 capital stock
Table 4. Paper manufacturing machines installed or rebuilt as a percent of 1995 capital stock, versus capital expenditures by paper and paperboard mills, 1983-95
Expenditure data are from the Census Bureau and from the National Council of the Paper Industry for Air and Stream Improvement.

The increased use of recycling equipment also carries productive efficiencies, compared with the use of wood fibre. Most grades of recycled paper appear to use less energy in production and produce less air pollution, although some grades require more purchased electricity.(38) According to one study, recycling 1 ton of materials in a typical curbside recycling program can save at least $183 worth of electricity, after deducting the cost of transportation to collect the materials.(39) Many types of paper are produced less expensively using recycled content, while most use some virgin fibre.(40)

Furthermore, using recovered paper can provide more flexibility in production. Imbalances in the supply of wood pulp are easily corrected for if manufacturers have the ability to substitute recovered paper. While recovered paper has a limited number of “lives” and is used in small quantities in most products, it can be recycled 5 to 8 times. As a result, manufacturers are using more of this resource. Use of recycled paper is forecast to increase as mill capacity for recovered pulp more than doubles between 1994 and 1998.(41) Lower energy costs, lower raw material costs, and lower labour costs per ton of output have resulted in a more efficient industry.

An increasing amount of output was produced in mills, with hours worked declining, between 1966 and 1995. (See chart 5.) Thus, labour productivity, as measured by output per hour, more than doubled over this period; the gains were not steady, but followed business cycle movements. Productivity gains over the period in pulp, paper, and paperboard mills were greater, on average (4.5 percent per year), than in paper industry components that used the output of these mills (folding paperboard boxes, 2.6 percent; corrugated solid fibre boxes, 3.8 percent; paper and plastic bags, 1.2 percent).

The confluence of consumer participation in recycling, improvements in technology, increased consumption of paper products, and liberalization of trade have had an enormous influence on employment in paper-related industries. Technological changes, while costly, have facilitated increased output of recycled products as improvements in efficiency and output quality are attained.

Footnotes

  1. “1996 Statistics. Data through 1995”, (American Forest and Paper Association), p. 2.
  2. Employment data are from the Current Employment Statistics survey and appear in various issues of Employment Hours, and Earnings. Data expressed in annual averages unless otherwise noted.
  3. See Paper Task Force Report (at p. 172), a voluntary, private-sector initiative sponsored by the Environmental Defense Fund, which developed recommendations for purchasing paper that reduce environmental impact while meeting business needs.
  4. American Museum of Papermaking.
  5. Technology and labour in Pulp, Paper, Paperboard, and Selected Converted Industries, Bulletin 2443 (Bureau of Labour Statistics, 1994), p. 3.
  6. Using recycled newspapers from an average residential recycling program saved 11.4 million BTU per ton of material compared to using virgin materials, according to The Role of Recycling in Integrated Solid Waste Management to the Year 2000 (Stamford, CT, Franklin Associates, Ltd. for Keep America Beautiful Inc., 1994), pp. 6-12, appendix I-49.
  7. “What’s the Outlook for Paper?” Biocycle, 96, pp. 78-80.
  8. SIC 261 manufactures pulp, SIC 262 manufactures paper, and SIC 263 produces paperboard. SIC 265 produces paperboard containers and boxes from purchased paperboard. SIC 267 produces various forms of converted paper products, such as sanitary paper products, paper and plastic bags, coated laminated paper, and others, from purchased paper and paperboard.
  9. Recycling is a large component of SIC 5093, but this category includes metals and minerals as well as other scrap materials.
  10. “MRF Growth was substantial in 1995,” World Wastes, 1996, p. 6.
  11. “Materials recovery facilities: A 1996 Update,” Biocycle, 1996, pp. 83-84.
  12. Ibid, p. 83.
  13. Ibid, p. 84.
  14. “1996 Statistics. Data through 1995”; and monthly statistical summaries of the American Forest and Paper Association.
  15. Source Reduction. It’s a Bare Necessity, (North Carolina Recycling Association and North Carolina Office of Waste Reduction 1995), p. 46.
  16. RISI Long-Term Pulp and Paper Review (Bedford, MA, Resource Information Systems Inc., 1995), p. 52.
  17. According to “1996 Statistics,” production of newsprint is also growing. In 1980, we produced approximately 40 percent newsprint consumed, while today we are producing over one-half.
  18. More efficient use of paper by publishers may explain growing circulation coincident to reductions in the tonnage of newsprint consumed.
  19. According to data compiled by McCann-Erickson, a prominent research and information consulting firm in the advertising industry, the print-related share of advertising expenditures has ranged from 56.5 percent in 1980 to 57.2 percent in 1994.
  20. “In so Many Word; How Tecnology Reshapes the Reading Habit,” American Demographics, 1997.
  21. Ibid.
  22. “1996 Statistics,” p. 2; and U.S. Department of Commerce, National Trade Data Bank.
  23. “Global Growth in U.S. Pulp and Paper Exports,” American Papermaker, 1995; and “1995 Statistics,” p. 81.
  24. “’95 another banner year for exports,” Journal of Commerce Special Report, 1996.
  25. Measured by product value, not tons. Data are from U.S. Department of Commerce, National Trade Data Bank.
  26. “Exports Fuel Paper Firms’ Sales,” Investors Business Daily. 15, 1995, p. A3.
  27. “Global Growth in U.S. Pulp and Paper Exports,” American Papermaker, 1995, pp. 43-49.
  28. Market barriers should be gradually reduced over this period as the result of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (most recently, the Uruguay Round), NAFTA,, and the USA-Japan Paper Agreement.
  29. According to the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency, paper and paper products accounted for 37.6 percent of landfill waste in 1993.
  30. See the 1995 and 1996 data summaries of the American Forest and Paper Association p. 57.
  31. The most important uses for recycled paperboard are folding cartons, corrugated containers, paper tubes, wallboard facings, book covers and binders, and insulation board. See “Recycled paperboard market pricing reacts to weaker demand and lower wastepaper costs,” Pulp and Paper, vol. 70, no. 6, p. 13.
  32. The Environmental Defense Fund developed a task force including institutions such as Duke University, Johnson & Johnson, NationsBank Corporation, McDonald’s, the Prudential Insurance Co., and Time, Inc., which together purchase more than $1 billion in printing and writing papers and share the common goal of finding ways to use environmentally preferable paper.
  33. “Buying Recycled: Investing Dollars to Close the Loop:” World Wastes, 1994, p. 38.
  34. “Banner Year for Paper Recovery at U.S. Mills,” Biocycle, 1997, p. 11.
  35. Published since 1960, Biocycle is a prominent magazine on composting and recycling.
  36. “1995 Statistics. Data through 1994” (American Forest and Paper Association, 1995), p. 66.
  37. Paper Task Force Report.
  38. Paper Task Force Report, table A-1-A-5. Most grades show a significant savings in energy used in production competed to virgin manufacturing processes.
  39. According to “Advantage Recycle: Assessing the Full Costs and Benefits of Curbside Recycling,” a report by the Environmental Defense Fund 31 percent of the savings was attributable to newspaper versus other recyclable products.
  40. See Paper Task Force Report, ch. 3, p. 68. Refers to linerboard, corrugating medium, newsprint, specialty uncoated printing and writing paper, among others. However, unsorted office paper is an example of one type which is more costly to produce using recycled pulp.
  41. “What’s the Outlook for Paper?” Biocycle, June 1996, vol. 37, no. 6, pp. 78-80.
    Cynthia Engel is an economist in the Office of Employment and Unemployment Analysis, Bureau of Labour Statistics.

Taking Back the Trash: Comparing European Extended Producer Responsibility and Take-Back Liability to U.S. Environmental Policy and Attitudes.

Abstract

The European Union and many individual European countries have in recent years developed waste management schemes that require manufacturers to take back products at the end of their useful life and shoulder responsibility for their recycling or disposal. The United States currently has no such national scheme. As the generation of waste increases, the United States will likely be forced to examine the merits of such a national policy.

The traditional approach to environmental liability and the individualistic culture of the United States, however, present unique obstacles to take-back mandates. The Author addresses those obstacles and possible solutions to them. The feasibility of developing such a system in the United States is also examined. The Author argues that such an environmental liability scheme could be developed in the United States, although there are many lessons to be learned from the systems used by members of the European Union.

Table of Contents

  • Introduction
  • Waste Disposal and Environmental Control
    • Introduction to Take-Back Laws
    • Take-Back Laws in Europe
      • European Union
      • Individual States
    • In Search of a National Take-Back Scheme: Waste Management in the United States
  • Social and Cultural Attitudes in an Epr Framework
    • A Western Cultural Divide.” Europe and the United States
    • Social Differences: Implications for Take-Back Laws
      • Criticisms of EPR
      • American Environmental and Social Attitudes
        • Environmental Attitudes
        • Implications of Social Attitudes for Environmental Problems
  • Take-Back: A Solution for the United States?
    • Developing a Regulatory Scheme: Legislative Feasibility
    • Domestic Legal Roadblocks
    • Attitudes as Barriers
  • Recommendations
  • Conclusion

Introduction

In 2001, the United States alone produced more than 7.8 billion tons of trash. (1) Increased waste generation is not unique to the United States; it is a global problem that will not go away. (2) Recycling is a popular solution, but there is room for growth in the development of waste management techniques) The speed at which technological development makes products obsolete is a growing problem. (4) An estimated 60 million new computers enter the U.S. market every year. (5) New product development creates an even faster growing pile of electronic waste as old products are discarded. It is estimated that by 2007, 500 million computers will be obsolete and in need of a place for disposal. (6) As the problem of waste generation continues to grow, governments struggle to create new coping strategies.

The European Union and individual European countries have implemented extended producer responsibility legal mandates to address rapid waste generation. (7) Extended producer responsibility, also known as “take-back,” requires manufacturers and sellers of products to take back from the consumer used products at the end of their useful life and to pay for their recycling and disposal. (8) The first country to adopt such a strategy was Germany. (9) Germany’s policy in turn inspired the European Union to issue directives for packaging materials, waste, end-of-life automobiles, and other environmental problems, (l0) The popular European approach is to create private entities to contract with manufacturers for disposal, (11) This approach is one, however, that does not come without obstacles, including high costs. (12)

This Note explores the mandates adopted by the European Union and individual European states and examines the feasibility of their implementation in the United States. Part II outlines the current extended producer responsibility schemes in Europe and the current waste disposal system in the United States. Part III examines the societal and cultural differences that account for varying environmental attitudes in Europe and the United States, with a focus on Germany. Part IV discusses the feasibility of developing national take-back requirements in the United States by examining legislative obstacles and other barriers. Part V offers a conclusion and recommendation for the United States that builds on the strengths of the European regimes’ schemes while recognizing the weaknesses of those plans.

Waste Disposal and Environmental Control

Introduction to Take-Back Laws

In response to the growing problem of excessive waste, several countries adopted liability schemes in which manufacturers must take responsibility for their products, attempting to slow the filling of landfills and the release of hazardous substances from discarded products. (13) Such laws, known as “take-backs,” are requirements imposed on manufacturers, importers, and sellers to take back their products from end users at the end of the product’s useful life. (14)

One catalyst to the emergence of take-backs is the growing support for “producer responsibility.” (15) This idea of extended producer responsibility (EPR) focuses on creating producer responsibility after the product is sold, when manufacturers traditionally cease to be responsible for their products, (16) The greatest take-back activity has been in Europe, where government-sponsored take-back initiatives arose from concerns about scarce landfill space and potentially hazardous substances in component parts. (17) The United States, in contrast, imposes no take-back requirements at the federal level, partly because the U.S. Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) lacks the authority to promulgate them. (18)

Take-backs challenge the traditional view that “a product’s price reflects the producer’s costs of manufacture, distribution, and marketing plus a profit margin.” (19) Normally, once the product is sold, the manufacturer no longer has responsibility for its ultimate disposal. (20) Therefore, all costs of waste disposal are paid by the consumer, typically through municipal taxes. (21) Manufacturers have had little incentive to reduce the wastes associated with product disposal because they have not paid these costs. (22)

The main goal of EPR is to reduce pollution that results from a product’s disposal. (23) The other goals of EPR take-back laws, however, have much more long-term significance. (24) James Salzman asserts that the additional goals of EPR include (1) encouraging companies to design products for reuse, recyclability, and materials reduction; (2) correcting market signals to the consumer by incorporating waste management costs into the product’s price; and (3) promoting innovation in recycling technology. (25) Take-backs make these goals a reality by creating incentives for companies to redesign their products, incorporating safer materials and making products easier to recycle and reuse. (26)

EPR is an extension of the “polluter pays” principle, which traditionally justifies charging producers for all the pollution caused by production.(27) Under take-back laws, when the manufacturer places a product on the market, that manufacturer must also pay for its eventual disposal. (28) Under this system, consumers still pay for the waste management of the packaging, but the increased costs are paid in the form of higher prices rather than in taxes. (29) Under EPR, producers in effect accept responsibility when they design products to minimize their environmental impact, and they accept legal, physical, and economic responsibility for the environmental effects of their products, (30) “In terms of legal doctrine, take-back laws may be loosely described as transforming the manufacturer’s legal relationship with its product by imposing a future property interest which vests upon disposal.” (31)

Take-Back Laws in Europe

European Union

The European Union (EU) recently adopted a directive on waste electrical and electronic equipment (WEEE). (32) The purpose of this directive is to prevent the production of WEEE and also to encourage reuse and recycling of such waste, (33) The directive requires Member States to encourage design and production methods that take into account the later dismantling and recovery of their products, (34) The WEEE directive sets a goal that by 2005 a system will be in place to allow final holders of a product to return waste free of charge, with distributors taking responsibility for disposal of the waste. (35) Member States must also ensure that users of electrical equipment have access to information about the requirement not to dispose of WEEE and the collection systems available. (36)

The EU also adopted a directive restricting the use of certain hazardous substances in electrical and electronic equipment. (37) One objective of this directive is to contribute to the environmentally sound recovery and disposal of WEEE. (38) This directive ensures that after July 1, 2006, new electrical and electronic equipment put on the market will not contain hazardous materials. (39)

The EU also created a liability regime for packaging. The European Packaging Directive came into force in 1994, setting boundary conditions and objectives that must be transposed into national legislation. (40) Under the Packaging Directive, each Member State must develop a system to take-back and recover or recycle used packaging. (41) The packaging waste may be incinerated–facilitating energy recovery–or recycled. (42) One goal for Member States is to collect between fifty and sixty-five percent of packaging waste and another goal is to recycle between twenty-five and forty-five percent of the total packaging material. (43)

The EU has also shown concern for disposal of end-of-life vehicles. (44) The EU found that consumers discard between eight and nine million vehicles yearly in the EU. (45) Furthermore, dismantling operations often cause a significant environmental hazard, as residues from shredding contain significant quantities of hazardous substances. (46) The Directive on End of Life Vehicles establishes a certification program under which only treatment facilities with permits can issue a certificate of destruction once a vehicle is discarded and becomes waste. (47) Authorized treatment facilities must carry out a number of operations related to correct de-pollution and removal of parts in order both to prevent pollution and to promote the reuse and recycling of end-of-life vehicles and their components. (48) Under this directive, the last owner of a vehicle can recover the cost of transferring the vehicle to an authorized treatment facility. (49)

Proponents of the EU approach describe it as harmonizing the measures of individual nations to promote the goals of protecting the environment and avoiding obstacles to trade within the EU. (50) For instance, the Packaging Directive allows individual countries to develop their own waste reduction plans by making choices between reuse, recycling, and energy recovery. (51) The Directive includes definitions for key terms to ensure baseline uniformity, but it allows flexibility by expressing goals in ranges. (52)

Individual States

Individual Member States of the EU have independently developed take-back programs. In 1991, Germany created the first EPR take-back program when it passed the Avoidance of Waste Packaging Ordinance, known as the “Toepfer Decree.” (53) The basic purpose of the Toepfer Decree is to require those who introduce packaging into the market to take it back after the product is sold. (54) The decree requires manufacturers to pay the recycling costs of packaging that is not eliminated or reused. (55)

In response to the Decree, a group of companies formed a new entity, the Duales System Deutschland (DSD), (56) authorized to work with local governments to collect recyclable packaging materials, (57) DSD contracts with companies to handle the recovery and the delivery of materials to sorting plants. (58) DSD then pays recyclers to take the materials. (59) Companies participating in the DSD program must apply for permission to use the “green dot” symbol on their packaging materials. (60)

DSD licenses the use of the green dot, which is placed on a product to signal that its packaging is recyclable and that DSD will handle the product’s packaging waste. (61) Retailers must return packaging without a green dot directly to the manufacturer. (62)
The DSD approach focuses on modifying industry practices rather than on creating extensive governmental regulations. (63) This system in Germany has led to creative “green” packaging ideas, which decrease the amount of packaging waste. (64) Thus, the German system has achieved the long-term EPR goals of encouraging companies to design with reuse and recycling in mind, as well as promoting technological innovation of product design. (65)

DSD and the German government implemented a plan for collection. The most widespread collection system in Germany is a curbside system in which consumers collect green dot packages in bags or bins provided to households. (66) DSD collects various product categories from the bins and bags and then passes on the materials to recyclers. (67) DSD selected these product categories for collection “based on evaluations of their environmental impacts, as well as their potential for reuse and recyclability.” (68)

The Toepfer Decree stimulated the enactment of the European Packaging Directive. (69) The German approach to solid waste disposal affected the thinking of both European and U.S. policymakers. (70) DSD founded PRO-Europe, “an organization uniting all recovery organizations using the [g]reen [d]ot under the EU directive.” (71) PRO-Europe grants national recovery and collection systems founded to implement the Packaging Directive the right to use the dot. (72) By 2001, ten EU Member States had implemented the green dot system: Belgium, Germany, France, Ireland, Luxembourg, Italy, Sweden, Austria, Portugal, and Spain. (73)

France has also developed comprehensive take-back legislation, distinguishing itself as one of the European leaders in EPR implementation. In 1992, France passed Decree No 92-377 regarding packaging waste. (74) A French firm, Eco-Emballages SA, organized a system to collect and recover household packaging that is designed to meet the requirements of the French Packaging Decree. (75) Article 4 of the Decree stipulates that any producer, importer, or other entity responsible for marketing a product contribute to or make provision for the disposal of all of its packaging waste. (76) Eco-Emballages is a private limited-liability company that serves as an interface between industry and local authorities, (77) The company itself does not collect used household packaging. (78)

Rather, collection is done by local authorities, who contract with Eco-Emballages and in return receive support for their collection and sorting of waste. (79)
Similar to Germany, France uses the green dot system, (80) Since 1996, more than ninety percent of the consumer products in France utilize the green dot. (81) The use of the green dot in France is the result of a 1992 Eco-Emballages contract with the DSD. (82) In France, a producer’s financial contribution is determined according to a price scale that charges a flat-rate amount plus an additional contribution based on the weight and material of the item. (83) Industrial firms show initiative in their willingness to take back and recycle the packaging collected; arrangements known as “sectoral undertakings.” (84) The undertakings are for specific materials, including steel, aluminum, paper, plastic, and glass, (85) Firms that take back the waste are categorized by the sectoral undertakings for each material, (86)

Taking a varied approach, France recently issued a used-tire recycling decree that will force distributors, importers, and manufacturers to take responsibility for collecting and eliminating the estimated sixty million tires discarded there each year. (87) Under the decree, tire manufacturers, importers, and distributors are in charge of the technical and financial organization of the collection and elimination of used tires. (88) The decree stipulates that service stations, car repair shops, and other distributors accept used tires from individuals on a no-fee basis. (89) But recycling charges may be assessed on the purchase of new tires, (90) Manufacturers and importers are expected to establish licensed, government-certified, industry-wide organizations that will gather the used tires and coordinate recycling and elimination. (91)

Other European Union Member States follow the lead of Germany and France. Austria, Denmark, Sweden, Finland, Ireland, Norway, Switzerland, the Netherlands, and the United Kingdom have all implemented some form of take-back initiatives. (92)

In Search of a National Take-Back Scheme: Waste Management in the United States

No comprehensive federal or state producer responsibility laws exist in the United States. (93) The head of the Natural Resources Defense Council stated that “regulatory or economic barriers might be preventing more companies from operating programs in which they take back equipment.” (94) In the United States, the concept of “product stewardship” is an alternative to producer responsibility. (95) Product stewardship proposes a system of responsibility shared by customers, retailers, local governments, and manufacturers for disposing of products at the end of their useful life. (96)

Some programs resembling take-backs exist in the United States, however. Nearly all states and the District of Columbia have implemented some type of oil recycling program. (97) For example, a Massachusetts statute requires every service station, marina, or retail outlet that sells automobile lubricating oil to install and maintain waste-oil retention facilities. (98) Surveys show widespread acceptance of this program, (99) creating an example of a well-received take-back program in the United States.

Although the United States lacks large-scale take-back regulations, there are alternative methods for handling waste. For instance, landfill bans are a common tool for encouraging recycling. (100) States vary widely, however, on the degree and variety of landfill bans imposed, ranging from no statewide bans (but allowing for local bans) to bans on a wide variety of materials, (101) Although landfill bans can be an effective way to ensure environmentally compatible disposal, they fall short of guaranteeing actual recycling of materials. (102) “[R]ather than aiming at reduction, the bans focus more on making the consumer choose proper disposal.” (103)

Recycling is a major strategy in the United States for waste management. Major programs aimed at the recycling of packaging materials include minimum content laws, labeling laws, and collection programs, specifically bottle bills and curbside recycling. (104) In addition, several states and the District of Columbia mandate that newsprint contain a minimum amount of recycled paper and establish purchase preferences based on the amount of its recycled content. (105) Also, green labeling in the United States is done on a voluntary basis, but it is seen as a way to clarify the recycling process by reminding consumers to recycle and to help establish preferences in shopping, (106) Federal Trade Commission guidelines have been established to deal with requirements that must be met by a company before it claims a product to be environmentally friendly. (107)

Curbside recycling is the most popular mechanism for recycling in the United States. (108) Under such systems, residents place their recyclable garbage into different containers on the curb for pickup. (109) Curbside recycling is available to more than half of the citizens of the United States and nearly every state has implemented such a program. (110)

Another U.S. approach to recycling is through Deposit-Refund Laws, commonly known as “bottle bills,” which are used in some states and are seen as being detrimental to curbside programs because they result in removal of some materials from curbside bins, thereby reducing the value of scrap material recovered through curbside programs. (111) Under bottle bills, distributors and retailers charge deposits on glass, plastic, and aluminum beverage containers. (112) Retailers must take back empty containers, refund the deposit, and pass the empty containers on to distributors. (113) Bottle bills make it more expensive, by amounts varying from state to state, to throw a bottle away than to recycle it. (114) Such recycling schemes establish a mindset and framework for the disposing of waste in a productive manner.

Some large U.S. companies voluntarily take back their own products. (115) A collation of groups called the Computer TakeBack Campaign recently issued report cards evaluating take-back programs used by computer companies. (116) Following its practice in European countries of taking back used computers from individual consumers, Dell recently implemented a policy in the United States whereby it will take back any printer for free when a customer purchases a new Dell printer, and the company will soon implement the same type of system for computers. (117) Hewlett-Packard actively supports state take-back legislation, including recent proposals in Maine and Minnesota. (118) Sony started a recycling program to take back its electronic products in Minnesota by subsidizing the cost of recycling electronics collected and allowing recyclers to earn a profit. (119) Despite these positive efforts, the Computer TakeBack Campaign concluded that the current state of electronics recycling is “unacceptable,” ranging from only two to ten percent. 120

Some municipalities and states in the United States, however, have attempted to implement EPR-type programs. For example, the city of Santa Clarita, California, introduced a diaper-recycling program. (121) Santa Clarita came close to creating a take-back ordinance, but it missed the mark by using general tax revenues instead of requiring the diaper companies to fund the effort. (122) In 2001, the Nebraska Legislature considered banning the dumping of electronic equipment in state landfills and imposing a fee on the sale of new televisions and computers to help fund recycling programs. (123)

In 2002, California proposed a bill that would charge consumers a fee on the sale of new computers and televisions, as well as require a warning label on televisions disclosing the hazardous materials contained inside. (124) Not long after, the Electronics Industry Alliance (EIA) polled consumers for reaction to pending legislation and found that most consumers would buy from out-of-state retailers to avoid the fee. (125) Based on this reaction, legislators dropped the proposal. (126)

Still, wide-scale changes in product take-back and recycling could be on the way in the United States. Environmental groups advocate action regarding electronic waste, because it is the nation’s fastest growing environmental problem, is known to be toxic, and causes long-term contamination when disposed in landfills. (127) The Northwest Product Stewardship Council, a member of the National Electronics Product Stewardship Initiative (NEPSI), proposed a national funding system for recycling electronic equipment in which consumers would pay a recycling fee at the time of purchase. (128)

David Stitzhal, a spokesperson for the council, recently commented that the consumer fee would diminish over time as manufacturers would begin to absorb some of the cost in a shift toward a “partial cost internalization fee.” (129) But this financing system has sparked intense debate, and after three years of national negotiations, NEPSI has yet to reach an agreement on how to finance such a system. (130) Despite these efforts, environmental groups doubt that any NEPSI agreement will ever pass the current Congress; they claim that state legislatures will move in to fill the void. (131)

Social and Cultural Attitudes in an Epr Framework

A Western Cultural Divide: Europe and the United States

The preference for extended producer responsibility outside the United States reflects a belief that EPR is consistent with the concept of the “polluter pays” principle. (132) Perhaps the absence of such a regime in the United States reflects on citizens’ reluctance to embrace a polluter-pays principle in a traditional manufacturing context. Under such a context, traditional manufacturers are characterized as polluters simply for creating products and selling them to the public. Whatever the cause, the United States continues to lag behind the European Union in waste reduction, particularly electronic waste reduction. (138)

Comparison between the United States and Germany is a useful way to evaluate differences in environmental laws and attitudes. (134) There are many similarities between Germany and the United States, because both are modern, industrial consumer societies. (185) But the two countries differ in many ways. (136) The United States is much larger, with many large regions that lack extensive industry and have low population densities. (137) The vast natural resources of the United States result in the lower costs of materials such as paper, metals, and plastics. (138) Furthermore, a national waste-collection plan makes less sense in the United States because of the great distances between population centers and the industrial facilities that process waste, (139)

German and U.S. recycling rates vary. For example, in 1995 Germany recycled sixty-nine percent of its packaging, while the United States recycled only 40.1 percent in 1996. (140) Germany and the United States recover similar percentages of paper and steel, but Germany also recycles much higher percentages of its glass and plastics. (141) These differences lead to the question, what about these two countries produce varying results?

One cause may simply be that “[t]he American people are a younger culture, with a stronger sense of individual freedom and personal autonomy.” (142) Voluntary action might produce better results in the United States than the inevitable “feet dragging” that will occur under environmental laws. (143) Marco Verweij makes an interesting comparison of U.S. and German environmental policies by examining the regulatory differences between the Great Lakes and the Rhine River. (144) Finding that industrial discharges into the Great Lakes in the United States were more toxic than discharges into German’s Rhine River despite stricter legislation in the United States, Verweij asserts that this difference is explained in part by the voluntary measures taken by German companies. (145) By the mid1980s, factories along the Rhine had already reduced their discharges to a greater degree than required by the more stringent 1991 standards yet to come; in other words, voluntary over-compliance exceeded even the future expectations of the German government.

(146) In contrast, U.S. corporations along the Great Lakes consistently resist water protection efforts and refuse to accept the standards promulgated by the EPA. (147) Thus, these companies have not voluntarily exceeded legally mandated standards in the Great Lakes area. This example is illustrative of different attitudes and approaches toward environmental regulation in the United States and Germany. The politics surrounding water standards have been more contentious in the United States, as is indicated by the deeper disagreements about the problems and the best solutions. (148)

Verweij asserts that a variety of factors account for the difference. Among the factors are moral differences and state-society arrangements (including executive and judiciary branches and businesses). (149) Another factor is American exceptionalism, a national ideology that emphasizes liberty and individualista. (150) In contrast, European values place greater emphasis on hierarchy, authority, and deference. (151) Another reason for the U.S.’s contentious environmental policies is a common mistrust of government, especially on the part of businesses. (152)
In turning to the state-society arrangements, the involvement of non-governmental actors in environmental policy-making creates challenges, (153) In the Rhine valley, non-governmental actors have fewer such opportunities. (154)

For example, under the Clean Water Act, private groups can sue the EPA or state agencies for failing to enforce environmental regulations, and they can sue private companies not obeying the law. (155) This policy is not conducive to achieving a meeting of the minds. (156) Furthermore, the structural differences between the U.S. federal government and the parliamentary system used by used many European countries helps account for the vast policy differences. (157) Under the U.S.’s presidential system, legislators have less responsibility for implementation of the laws they make, which gives them leeway to make unrealistic laws. (158) Also, a presidential system gives interest groups a chance to influence governmental policies, mostly by lobbying members of relevant Congressional committees. (159)

Furthermore, in a parliamentary system, ministries confer with each other in a lengthy process of creating law, while in a presidential system agencies develop policies in isolation from each other, (160) Thus, under a presidential system, environmental laws may be subjected to more outside challenges, inspired by unrealistic goals, influenced by special interest groups, and affected by agency isolation–all factors that impede implementing national legislation. (161)

The corporate climates of Europe and the United States also differ. In many European countries, corporatism has long been popular. (162) Corporatism is a system of special interest representation of units organized into a limited number of singular, compulsory, noncompetitive, hierarchically ordered, and functionally differentiated categories. (163) Under this system, organizations negotiate under the watchful eye of the government, and associations try to find a consensus that is acceptable to all parties. (164) This system creates an easy means for industry-wide environmental policy debate. (165) European corporatism is not widely accepted in the United States, which has instead adopted pluralism. (166) Under pluralism, individual actors fend for themselves, leaving little motivation for voluntary over-compliance with environmental regulations. (167) This “fend for yourself’ attitude could affect the way companies and individuals make environmental decisions.

Social Differences: Implications for Take-Back Laws

Criticisms of EPR

A number of managerial problems arise with the implementation of extended producer responsibility policies. Obstacles to such implementation include

  1. product design that enables cost-effective disassembly as well as high-quality recovery;
  2. the development of secondary end markets to sell the recovered waste;
  3. the set up of collection systems; and
  4. making information available for all decision makers. (168)

Perhaps there is a lesson to be learned from the EPR schemes implemented in other countries. Germany’s success in creating packaging alternatives and promoting innovative technology came with significant financial costs. (169) Unrealistic goals nearly bankrupted the program. (170) Thus, Germany learned the hard way that failure to deal with certain economic realities threatens the viability of take-back programs. (171)

Some critics believe EPR schemes that force producers to become “expert garbage collectors” will make them inept at producing their own products. (172) As a result, critics claim, product design could suffer, as most changes might be made solely for environmental reasons. (173) For example, manufacturers might switch from plastic components to metal because metal is easier to recycle, whereas plastics might provide other benefits to design and ease of packing and consumer use. (174)

Financing EPR schemes is yet another hurdle to successful implementation. One such issue is whether take-back schemes should require point-of-sale fees or force companies to internalize the costs. (175) Companies are split on the issue, but a national EPR scheme would require uniformity in financing. (176) Even if manufacturers do reach a much-needed consensus, a hurdle exists in finding support from retailers for a financing system. (177) So far, U.S. retailers have not discussed such a project in the United States. (178)

American Environmental and Social Attitudes
Environmental Attitudes

“The American environmental movement encompasses a variety of environmental organizations, ideologies, and approaches.” (179) The logic behind American environmental regulation stems from the fundamental paradox that “individuals acting rationally in pursuit of their own interests will produce a desired collective outcome.” (180) As discussed below, a variety of common perceptions about the environment and environmental regulations form many obstacles to implementing EPR-type regulations in the United States. (181)

From a historical perspective, industrial polluters were the source of the most significant environmental and related human-health problems. (182) Large industrial polluters were perceived as easier to regulate from an administrative standpoint, being fewer in number and more homogeneous than second-generation sources. (183) In the early days of U.S. environmental regulation, “[t]he limited scientific understanding of the relationship between any specific emission source and the environmental conditions affected may have made the prospect of designing and supporting controls” on individual companies a daunting task. (184)

Furthermore, fear of underrepresentation of unorganized interests, such as environmental groups, led to accusations of a pro-industry bias in the environmental policy process. (185) Thus, industry regulation perhaps conveyed a social meaning to the public that industrial polluters were the source of environmental problems. (186)

Currently, U.S. environmental laws impose a command-and-control approach to regulation that comprises three basic beliefs: (1) that it is possible to contain environmental contamination; (2) that it is possible to disperse contaminants to a point that they are no longer a threat; and (3) that it is possible to regulate pollution “at the end of the pipe.” (187) But statutes based on these beliefs inadequately ensure protections of the environment because they only attempt to mitigate pollution after it has been created. (188) As pollution increases and accumulates, it becomes less feasible to dilute and disperse it at the end of the pipe. (189)

Furthermore, the classic “experimental” policy-making approach used in the United States makes environmental problems difficult to solve with legislation. (190) Verweij illustrates that U.S. citizens are more individualistic and that the U.S. political system is less immune than parliamentary systems to challenges to environmental policies. (191) A consequence is the possibility of irreversible harm if the environmental policies adopted are ineffective. (192)

Governmental regulatory activity, however, generates information that promotes environmental protection. (193) Although “regulatory programs are criticized for their clumsiness and expense, they do force private actors to take cognizance of the environmental consequences of their plans….” (194) Such regulations force firms to place environmental costs on their balance sheets. (195) Thus, regulations themselves can create environmental considerations.

A more general obstacle is the universally recognized uncertainty that surrounds environmental issues. (196) Common characteristics of environmental problems create this obstacle. (197) One characteristic is the substantial geographic distances between harms and the events that cause them. (198) Also, environmental problems can take years to manifest or for their full scope to be understood. (199) This means irreversible environmental damage may occur before the costs of it are realized. (200) Environmental damage also frequently results from multiple causes, and it can be difficult to sort out the extent to which each causes the problem. (201) “[U]ncertainty increases the difficulty of addressing environmental problems” because it makes them easier to ignore. (202)

Adding further difficulty, value conflicts invariably arise when environmental problems are addressed. (203) Value conflicts in the environmental context are fundamental and often zero-sum with no win-win solution possible. (204) No one can increase the amount of air, water, or land–which means using those resources for one purpose precludes using them for another. (205) At the least, this creates a perception (if not a reality) that businesses cannot produce to their full potential through utilization of the earth’s resources while maintaining a healthy environment and lasting natural resources.

Another characteristic feature of environmental problems is that they require long-term solutions. (206) Also, the need for both durable and flexible solutions suggests institutional and philosophical problems. (207) Institutionally, policy creates a maintainable path while providing flexibility to adjust to natural changes. (208) Philosophically, policymakers must ask whether to bind future generations to the path of environmental protection, without realizing what future values will be. (209) Thus, those making decisions about environmental resources today have no way of knowing their worth in the future, which could cause either under or overestimation of their value.

A common obstacle to environmental protection is the “tragedy of the commons.” Environmental resources have an “unpropertied” character, meaning they cannot generate individual wealth. (210) Environmental resources are “open access resources” because they have no owners and are open to all comers. (211) Because no one person owns environmental resources, they are subject to the late of every commons: “over-exploitation and under-investment,” “depletion and decimation.” (212) Also, there is great investment in scientific and technological information that increases the value of privately held resources, and slower rates of investment into information about the consequences of exploitation of public resources, resulting in many information gaps and research lags regarding shared environmental resources. (213) In short, concerns about public resources (e.g., landfills) do not produce in individuals the same willingness to invest as do private resources because individuals do not see the same opportunities to profit from public resources.

Furthermore, studies reveal that Americans are unaware of their individual contributions to existing environmental problems. (214) During much of the 1990s, the National Environmental Education and Training Foundation (NEETF), which conducted surveys of public knowledge of environmental issues, found that the public knows less than it believes. (215) This phenomenon is part of a larger problem of the disparity between the public’s view of the relative magnitude of environmental risks and the experts’ view of those risks. (216) The result of a misinformed public is the creation of many environmental myths in which individuals do not see their role in creating environmental problems. (217) Despite this result, public awareness of the complexity of environmental problems is growing, as is public support for environmental initiatives. (218) At the same time, there is a distrust of “big government,” which causes the public to desire smaller, more manageable efforts on the local level. (219)

Implications of Social Attitudes for Environmental Problems

In 1996, sixty-six percent of Americans believed that the goals of economic growth, environmental protection, and health and happiness of people were simultaneously achievable. (220) A challenge posed by environmental problems is that they cannot be solved by persons’ individual choices. (221) For any one person rationally to take action, there must be some assurance in environmental policies that others will also do so. (222)

For example, no matter how concerned any given individual is about an environmental problem, such as global warming, there is little one person acting alone can do to solve the problem. If one person stopped driving and installed a solar heat and electricity system in their home, emissions of carbon dioxide change only negligibly. (223) That person would see his efforts as futile, and would not be motivated to reduce emissions within his control. (224) If individuals notice others behaving as if they do not value environmental protection, those individuals may wrongly conclude that environmental protection is not widely valued. (225)

These findings, taken together with the fact that the U.S. population is largely unaware of the impact of individual behavior on the environment, produce little surprise that the public has reacted negatively to attempts to change individual behavior. (226) U.S. federal environmental enforcement uses deterrence to induce compliance with environmental regulations. (227) Under the standard deterrence model, the assumption is that an individual will seek to maximize expected utility and thus will comply with environmental laws when the costs of noncompliance exceed the benefits. (228) Under this standard approach, individuals are not motivated to comply absent the threat of legal sanctions. (229)

Rational decision-making by individuals favors investments in scientific investigation where there is some potential for private gain–i.e., when the end product of the investigation can be turned into property. (230) Thus, that same rational decision-making neglects scientific investigation where the benefits may never become property, but may instead be diffused to the public at large, where payoffs may not come for years. (231) Information on such scientific and environmental subjects could have enormous social benefits, but because they are so dispersed, these subjects are likely to remain at most a matter of private concern to individual researchers. (232) This further illustrates the “tragedy of the commons” problem.

Regarding individual responsibility of household waste, consumer choice is determined by two considerations. (233) First, consumers look to see what is available, which is determined by what the industry puts into the market. (234) Second, socio-demographic factors and income play role in decisions because of their influence on lifestyle, attitudes, and awareness. (235) The people most likely to participate in recycling programs are those who are motivated to do so, but different motives underlie the behavior of different individuals. (236) Recyclers have motives different from non-recyclers; while neither is concerned about economic costs, non-recyclers are more concerned about the inconvenience of recycling. (237)

Motives to recycle and conservation competencies are the most important predictors of observed recycling behavior, while amount of effort required is another important factor. (238) These recycling behaviors will likely have an impact on the effectiveness of any take-back program, as consumers will have to participate by returning goods to manufacturers, either through curbside collection or returning to a collection location.

Ebreo and Vining found that community infrastructure does influence people’s attitudes toward recycling programs and policies during their studies of the motives and attitudes regarding recycling among residents of Champaign, Illinois. (239) In the early stages of solid waste planning, residents placed more emphasis on matters of personal convenience than on altruistic factors and adherence to social norms. (240) If recycling is highly convenient, the strengths of attitudes in favor of recycling and environmental protection are of little importance in predicting behavior; those weakly motivated to recycle are just as likely to recycle as those strongly motivated. (241)

External and internal norms also play a role in motivating environmental compliance. (242) Internal norms arise when an individual adopts a behavior as an obligation. (243) The perceived costs of violating an internal norm stem from the expected feelings of guilt and shame upon violation. (244) External norms include popular beliefs about social obligations; noncompliance may trigger social sanctions. (245) Thus, the perceived costs of violating an external norm are the sanctions expected when others learn of the norm violation. (246) The Schwartz norm activation theory suggests that the intensity of the obligation felt by the individual affects a norm’s influence on behavior. (247) Awareness of the consequences to the welfare of others stemming from an individual’s actions and an attribution of personal responsibility for causing or preventing those consequences both activate norms. (248) Laws and law enforcement can tie internal norms to concrete norms, thus leading to new behavioral intentions. (249) Therefore, enforcement of environmental laws could be achieved by providing information about the consequences of noncompliance and the individual’s ability to prevent those consequences. (250)

U.S. citizens now place increasing importance on protecting the environment. (251) “The lobbying and legislative successes of the American environmental movement have redefined the general public’s attitudes toward environmental policy problems.” (252) Fortunately, those attitudes have been redefined in moral or ethical terms. (253) These new attitudes create hope for the success of environmental protection regimes that require individual action, such as take-back laws.

This concept also applies to businesses. Businesses do consider environmental values in making decisions, at least in part because of environmental laws. (254) Governmental policy promotes consideration by businesses of environmental issues in two ways. (255) First, policy environmental protection by establishing standards to which businesses must comply. (256) Second, laws indirectly influence businesses by stigmatizing their violations of environmental laws. (257) Thus, environmental policies promote environmental protections in the decision making of businesses as well as for individuals.

Take-Back: A Solution for the United States?

Developing a Regulatory Scheme: Legislative Feasibility

The United States is unique among industrialized countries in not having any national EPR mandates. (258) At the present time, only individual companies in the United States have implemented take-back policies. (259) For example, Xerox earns substantial profits by taking back and remanufacturing the office equipment it produces. (260) Also, the carpet industry was the first in the United States to develop take-back programs. (261) While voluntary efforts continue to grow, particularly in the electronics industry, national take-back legislation is not foreseeable in the near future. (262) The lack of legislation may stem from pessimistic attitudes about federal environmental regulation, as illustrated by Congressman Earl Blumenauer:

For most of the last decade, environmental protection at the federal level has reached an impasse, as increasing concerns about the economic and social impacts of environmental regulation have led to the extension of important targets and deadlines as well as growing resistance to new protective legislation. When the federal government does act, initiatives providing long-term environmental protection are often sidetracked by issues that are shorter-term, more tangible, and easier to accomplish. Comprehensive environmental approaches are too often laid aside as overly complex or even impossible to implement. (263)

We will write
a custom essay
specifically for you
Get your first paper with
15% OFF
The National Electronics Product Stewardship Initiative met in June 2003 to study options for a nationwide electronic waste-recycling program. (264) All sides involved, including environmentalists, government officials, and industry leaders, voiced concerns about such a program. (265) Environmentalists are particularly concerned because they doubt that the process will produce a viable national solution for handling electronic waste. (266) A troublesome obstacle “is funding. Local governments and environmental groups want to charge consumers a front-end environmental fee for each unit they purchase to pay for the collection and recycling of scrap electronics.” (267)

But Hewlett-Packard’s Director of Global Policy, David Isaacs, believes that front-end fees are not fair or sound. (268) Hewlett-Packard has announced its “HP Proposal,” which would have manufacturers internally bear the costs of recycling end-of-life equipment. (269) The HP Proposal, based on the European Union’s Waste Electrical and Electronic Equipment Directive, called for manufacturer responsibility at least from the point of consolidation, leaving the details up to Member States. (270)

“With all three branches of the federal government–legislative, executive, and judicial–deeply involved with environmental issues, there are a number of ways to derail initiatives.” (271) Skeptics doubt that any legislation amenable to NEPSI will pass the current Congress. (272) According to Congressman Blumenauer, an increase of conservative thinking in Congress created a blocking of regulations, environmental or otherwise. (273) Furthermore, the U.S. high technology industry is eager to voice disapproval of such a plan, as are other industries. (274) Although NEPSI negotiations and planning continue, groups opposing any such legislation will be able to lobby for Congressional disapproval of such legislation. Resistance to such environmental regulations could spell big trouble for innovative EPR regulations.

David Wood, program director of GrassRoots Recycling Network, explained that “[a]t this juncture, there is far more likelihood of success taking place at the state level than at the national level. It is essential, therefore, that states forge ahead….” (275) However, there could be problems with states developing their own proposals for dealing with electronic waste. States that require reporting and take-back will have to notify all the manufacturers of the products to be taken back; (276) however, most computer parts are made in Asia, which could make enforcing take-back laws nearly impossible. (277) Furthermore, states and industries may prefer a national solution to recycling waste to a patchwork of varying state laws. (278) A study by the General Accounting Office illustrated that in trying to introduce new methods of enforcing environmental standards, state officials face problems not only in a lack of resources, but also in regulatory requirements and “cultural resistance” from federal counterparts. (279)

One problem with mandatory take-back programs has been identifying the responsible entity. (280) The problem is that costs are imposed on producers, so companies try to avoid being the responsible entity. (281) Another concern is that it is not always practical for companies to take back their own products. (282) However, some progress has been made. As David Stitzhal, coordinator of NEPSI, stated in February 2004, the electronics industry has at least acknowledged its responsibility. (283) What the industry is willing to do is unknown. (284)
Another impediment in the United States to such laws is the sheer size of the country. (285)

In comparing recycling in Germany and the United States, Donnelly notes how much larger the United States is and how driving long distances to collect materials becomes too expensive. (286) Thus, in such a geographically dispersed country such as the United States, it is more efficient for the materials to be simply thrown away. (287) A study of the German system reveals that a reduction of transport and secondary packaging would be successful in the United States, as it has helped to reduce landfill loads in Germany. (288) Some argue that adopting an entire take-back system would not work in the United States. (289)

Nonetheless, the U.S. systems for taking back waste oil and lead-acid batteries through state implemented programs under national policies are promising. (290) Thus, a national plan for taking back items such as packing materials and electronic waste will be successful on a national level if states implement such programs.
Despite these concerns, there are three major reasons why take-backs would be an attractive option for the United States. First, EPR programs shift environmental management expenses to the private sector by placing responsibility on producers. (291) Take-back laws are premised on the idea that waste management costs will be paid by individual consumers in the form of higher prices or consumer fees (or a combination thereof), instead of collectively with local tax revenues. (292) In fact, EPR programs coincide with the “polluter pays” principle, which according to classic economic theory can only operate by incorporating environmental costs into industry activities. (293) Therefore, if the U.S. government imposes take-back requirements on manufacturers industry and consumers will bear the costs directly.

Second, several states implemented programs involving advanced disposal fees, a weak form of take-back laws. (294) For example, EPR is mandated for the producers of lead-acid batteries, tires, and motor oil, and the disposal lees are reflected in the prices of those products. (295) Finally, U.S. companies already voluntarily practice EPR. (296) Such examples include the take-back schemes implemented by Xerox, Sony, Dell, Hewlett-Packard, and various companies in the carpet industry. (297)

In anticipation of an alternative to such voluntary schemes, the National Solid Wastes Management Association outlines four components of good electronic waste and recycling programs. (298) First, governments would build upon existing solid waste and recycling infrastructure for electronic waste collection and processing. (299) Second, advance recycling fees or take-back provisions would provide financial support for electronic waste recycling. (300) Third, environmental, health, and safety standards for the proper management of collected materials, including reporting and documentation procedures for end-markets, must be ensured. (301) Fourth, government officials would support programs that develop new processing technologies and new markets, especially those that use recycled content in new electronic products. (302) Also, in the case of take-back programs, those who rate and date electronic waste should be supported to ensure accountability. (303) All four components offer suggestions to current U.S. lawmakers.

A lesson is offered by the German program in establishing a national take-back system. Although German law mandates individual responsibility and sets overall material collection and recycling rates, it is the private collection organization that defines “recyclable” packaging and sets tariffs for inclusion in the program. (304) The privatization of these duties is a key element to the success of any take-back program.
If the United States were to adopt take-back programs, a decision would have to be made whether to focus on existing products or new products. (305) Selecting products to focus on is a critical policy issue. This issue is most critical for durable goods, including automobiles, electronic equipment, and carpets (which are all products that have been found to contribute to significant disposal problems). (306)

Domestic Legal Roadblocks

There are two major legal barriers to enacting nationwide take-back programs in the United States. First, anti-trust law is a barrier if a waste-collection monopoly is established, which is likely. (307) The packaging collection programs of European countries are all private nationwide monopolies. (308) Predictions are that “[i]f federal EPR take-back laws were implemented in the U.S…. it is likely a national joint venture like DSD would be created by the affected industries in order to manage the collection and end-use of the packaging of products.” (309) If such a monopoly is created, there would be four options for avoiding anti-trust law. (310)

First, Congress could restrict application of certain anti-trust requirements, although this is rare and usually subjects the activity to substantial federal oversight. (311) Second, Congress could use a standard under a rule of reason rather than per se for anti-trust action against certain ventures. (312) Third, legal precedent could shield the collection venture even if there were no anti-trust exemption included in take-back legislation, if the venture is the least drastic means to achieve the goals of the program. (313) Finally, Congress could opt not to provide any anti-trust protection, which would encourage competitive collection operations at a regional or national level. (314) Also, if the take-back program is introduced at a state level, the state action doctrine could exempt state collection industries from federal anti-trust enforcement if the program articulated a policy to displace competition and was actively supervised by state agents. (315) Thus, anti-trust laws do not present an insurmountable obstacle to the implementation of take-back legislation.

Another challenge to take-back proposals in the United States is in the Resource Conservation and Recovery Act (RCRA) regulation of hazardous substances. (316) The RCRA imposes a number of obstacles to the collection and recycling of hazardous waste, including the electronics that so badly need to be recycled. (317) Centers collecting any hazardous substances are classified as Treatment, Storage, or Disposal facilities (TSDs) under subtitle C, which would subject them to EPA certification requirements, increasing costs, and provide strong disincentives for collecting hazardous materials through a network. (318) In 2003, the EPA, recognizing this problem, proposed in 2003 to exclude certain hazardous materials targeted for recycling from the definition of hazardous waste. (319) Although environmental groups remain skeptical of exclusion of too many materials from RCRA, the EPA plans to continue to exclude such materials to ease product recycling. (320)

These legal issues leave open questions about what support the American legal system will provide for EPR initiatives. It appears, however, that Congress has the option of adjusting anti-trust law and environmental regulations to accommodate such programs. Perhaps such changes will create a more receptive legal community.

Attitudes as Barriers

The “law does much more than regulate behavior. It plays a key role in knitting the very fabric of society, creating the background against which people conduct their lives.” (321) In subtle ways, the law influences the values that communities espouse and follow. (322) Laws communicate messages to the public about their responsibilities help to shape attitudes.
“[T]he public’s short attention span and the media’s propensity to focus on controversy and quick fixes” discourage even handed discussions and articulation of complete explanations to today’s problems. (323) Today it seems that the easiest environmental issues to address are those in “stark black-and-white terms.” (324)

Unfortunately, the problem of waste piling up in landfills is not one that offers an easy solution. Thus, it is difficult to convey to the U.S. public the complex advantages and disadvantages of EPR and take-back requirements.

Ebreo and Vining’s study suggests hesitation on the part of both recyclers and non-recyclers about curbside collection. (325) Hesitation may have been caused by concerns about cost, but it also may represent a tendency of people to support programs that are familiar to them, rather than programs about which they have little knowledge or experience. (326) However, a previous study by Ebreo and Vining revealed that higher levels of participation in recycling followed the creation of curbside programs. (327)

A possible solution to overcoming public negativity about possible EPR mandates would be to educate the public on the benefits of such programs. Still, research on the role of educational programs in strengthening environmental values is ambiguous. (328) However, information campaigns increase knowledge and signal the importance of the desired behavior. (329) Empirical studies show that information about existing campaigns can increase recycling behavior. (330)

Furthermore, educational programs are not the only means by which the public’s opinions about solid waste programs are influenced. “Although it has not received a great deal of attention, the provision and implementation of programs themselves can have an effect on the public’s attitudes and motives as well as their behavior.” (331) Studies have shown that improving accessibility to recycling programs can result in higher levels of participation. (332) Through the use of laws, the public receives a message conveyed by a law, and that message can affect perceptions about the sources of the problem and on the social norms that develop in response to those perceptions. (333) Perhaps actually implementing an EPR collection system is the best way to garner public support for producer take-backs.

In further support of simply implementing a take-back program to improve awareness are the many ways in which laws shape behavior. (334) By their very existence, laws shape actions and attitudes. (335) First, laws shape technology by either encouraging or discouraging the development of new technologies. (336) That regulatory schemes produce incentives to innovate for purposes of environmental compliance lends support to the hope that U.S. manufacturers will alter products and create collection systems in order to make recycling easier at the end of useful life. (337) Second, laws shape institutions that determine the principles and values that motivate public actions. (338)

Laws in themselves tell to the public what they should value; thus, take-back laws can generate support from the public simply by existing and being enforced. (339) Laws can also encourage and discourage the development of particular capabilities. (340) Mandating EPR by law would ensure that manufacturers would invent the capability to take back their products. (341)

A barrier exists in the fact that an EPR take-back scheme would require action by individuals to return products to their manufacturers. (342) The United States has a long history of individuals failing to appreciate their own contributions to environmental problems and of resistance to attempts to regulate individual behavior. (343) Overcoming this mindset and empowering individuals to participate will likely be the largest hurdle in implementing a nationwide take-back system in the United States.

Recommendations

“As policymakers search for answers to the… waste disposal problem and seek to encourage recycling and other techniques, they should keep in mind the primary lesson of the German experiment: government policies cannot erase technical and economic realities, they can only influence them or be broken by them.” (344) “Those who wish to see the journey of environmental policy succeed should resist the forces that tend to squelch discussion of values.” (345) It is essential that EPR and take-backs be discussed in terms of the values they reveal. (346) In codifying EPR, the U.S. government will be adopting the polluter pays principle.

The first task will be the development of realistic goals. (347) The German government imposed an impossible burden on the DSD in setting recycling goals that were based on ideology rather than technical facts and economic realities. (348) Germany found that high goals for taking back and recycling materials like aluminum and steel were workable, but plastics were far too difficult and expensive to recycle at high rates. (349) The lesson for U.S. policymakers is to assess the costs of taking-back and recycling individual materials. As different industries likely will be responsible for different combinations of materials, the United States should create different collection and recycling goals and different timelines based on the feasibility of recycling different materials. Furthermore, the EU approach is a guide for the United States in developing legislation that will harmonize the states’ activities. The Packaging Directive’s combination of definitions (for uniformity) and ranges of targets (for flexibility) could help individual U.S. states implement programs while sustaining national goals, just as it did in the EU. (350)

In terms of waste prevention and reduction by industry in the United States, there is a need to move toward

  1. using less hazardous raw materials,
  2. product substitution and designing for reuse,
  3. using fewer composite materials in products,
  4. using recyclates,
  5. focusing on durability and extended product life, and
  6. increasing the importance of eco-design. (351)

In terms of waste reduction through consumer behavior, it is desirable to introduce

  1. products containing less hazardous materials,
  2. products containing recycled materials,
  3. longer-life products,
  4. repairable products, and
  5. a process for leasing or hiring products. (352)

Extended producer responsibility would influence on both companies and consumers to value these ideas. Consumers would likely focus on products that either last longer or are repairable if take-back laws forced them to finance the end-of-life recycling of products. For producers, taking end-of-life responsibility for their products seems likely to induce them to produce products that are less hazardous, more durable, easier to recycle, longer lasting, and more environmentally friendly.

In developing take-back schemes, the U.S. government can expect that interest groups will play a role and influence the specifics of any such plan. (353) Because of this aspect of the legislative process and the isolation of agencies under the presidential system, take-back schemes will take longer to develop in the United States than they did in Europe. (354) However, this does not make take-backs unfeasible for the United States. The U.S. government will likely support EPR at least in part because it shifts environmental expenses to the private sector. (355) Such support will have to overcome any political resistance to environmental laws.

The weaker forms of EPR enacted by states, the limited national plans for oil and batteries, and the voluntary programs undertaken by U.S. companies all lay a foundation for a national take-back program for various types of waste. If the United States were to adopt a national take-back plan, lawmakers would be challenging a basic principle of the current command and control approach to environmental regulation–namely, that it is possible to regulate at the “end of the pipe.” (356) Given the rate at which waste is piling up, changing that principle may be inevitable, and the U.S. government may be better off in recognizing its un-workability sooner.

The “fend for yourself” attitude prevalent among U.S. industries presents another obstacle to the implementation of EPR. (357) However, voluntary efforts from some companies are encouraging. Also, regulatory programs force firms to face environmental concerns in development and manufacturing of products. (358) In addition, environmental laws require firms to meet standards and create a stigma for those who do not. (359) Thus, businesses have less choice in complying with EPR mandates.

Individual compliance presents a greater challenge. Take-back legislation would require individuals to participate in returning their products to the manufacturers or retailers–or to participate in a curbside collection system. Individuals fail to see their own roles in creating problems; (360) therein lies the challenge of motivating all individuals to comply and behave as if they value the environment. A national set of legal obligations would ensure individual compliance under the standard theory of deterrence used in U.S. environmental laws. (361) Also, such an approach could be very beneficial in that laws themselves create norms, which in turn motivate individuals to act based on the wish to avoid either social sanctions or internal feelings of guilt or shame. Provisions directed toward individuals will be particularly helpful if they include information about the specific consequences of non-compliance, as this will help to trigger norms and feelings of obligation. (362)

Financing is another heated issue. Basic economics suggest that internalizing costs will be the only way to create an efficient system. (363) In accordance, the German and French approaches rely on the producers of products to fund take-back efforts. (364) But some manufacturers favor a system of front-end fees for consumers, and the debate on this point continues. (365) One of the traditional goals of EPR is to force manufacturers to internalize the costs of take-backs and reflect that internalization in the product’s price. (366) This approach seems to be a sound way to finance take-backs, but the challenge will be to force industries to reach such a consensus.

Another factor to consider is the collection of waste itself. If the United States models its EPR mandates after those in Europe, it will likely develop a private system for waste collection, similar to DSD or Eco-Emballages. There are differences between Eco-Emballages and DSD to consider in formulating a U.S. plan. First, Eco-Emballages does not itself collect waste, but DSD does. (367) Eco-Emballages merely subsidizes local municipalities that collect waste. (368) The French Eco-Emballages system makes more sense in a geographically vast country such as the United States. Because size is an obstacle to implementing a national collection program, (369) the Eco-Emballages approach is more feasible because it would build on the existing U.S. methods of collecting waste through local municipalities. This is preferable to a DSD-type system, which would require the creation of an entirely new national entity.

The green dot labeling system is another possibility for promoting an EPR system in the United States. Green labels would create awareness of a product’s recyclability. (370) Green dots are a simple plan that has worked throughout Europe to trigger the first step in the recycling process: consumers placing the product in the recycling loop. (371) The goal would be to create a perception among U.S. consumers that green dots create a responsibility on their part to begin the take-back process.

The policy of the National Solid Waste Management Association (NSWMA) lays out several helpful suggestions for take-backs that could serve as a guide for any U.S. policies. (372) For example, building on existing waste and recycling infrastructure would be especially helpful for individuals resistant to take-back requirements. Using that which is already in existence could make people feel as if take-backs were not as much of an extra burden.

The findings of Ebreo and Vining that non-recyclers are most worried about inconvenience lend further support to the use of existing infrastructure. (373) If current recycling systems are seen as convenient and are already used, adding other products to be taken back by manufacturers might not have a great effect. NSWMA also suggests reporting and documenting procedures, as well as the development of new processing technologies. Reporting and documenting would be an easy legislative move to make, as such requirements already exist in many U.S. laws, including RCRA. Also, take-back laws themselves would encourage the development of new technologies by firms looking to meet requirements in the most efficient way possible. (374)

Looking further down the road, the United States will need to consider whether to focus solely on take-back legislation or go a step further by promoting product redesign. The EU Hazardous Substances Directive provides an example of an approach that looks beyond keeping the waste out of landfills. (375) The directive’s ban on hazardous substances is an example of a possible follow-up approach that could be the subject of federal take-back legislation.

Conclusion

“We will never reach an environmental endpoint that allows us to maintain a permanent set of policy choices. We must, therefore, always be thinking about how well our current policy choices will prepare us for those we will face in the future.” (376) The problem of waste will not go away. As many discarded products make their way in to landfills at faster rates than ever before, the U.S. government will face the choice of whether to impose a national mandatory system of extended producer responsibility.

Given international trends, the United States may have no other option than to implement national take-back legislation. Luckily for the United States, the European models provide many lessons learned on take-backs and extended producer responsibility. The United States can use European models to develop a national EPR mandate while keeping in mind the need for flexibility and long-term thinking. The unique culture and legal structure of the United States requires and adjustment to the European example to create a new system that can comfortably require participation from government, industry, and individuals.

The development of a national take-back scheme in the United States is not only entirely feasible but also necessary. Waste will continue to pile up at even more rapid rates as the population increases and innovations in technology make more products obsolete. The details of financing and creating a national collection system will present obstacles, but the need for such a national system is ever-present.

  1. See EPA OFFICE OF SOLID WASTE AND EMERGENCY RESPONSE, RESOURCE CONSERVATION CHALLENGE: A YEAR OF PROGRESS, ANNUAL REPORT 2002-2003 1 (2004). Web.
  2. See Susan McInerney, Computer Firms Improve E-Waste Scores, but U.S. Still Lags Behind Japan, EU Efforts, 26 INT’L ENV’T REP. 108, 109, 2003.
  3. See Jim Glenn, The State of Garbage in America, BIOCYCLE. 1999, at 60 [hereinafter State of Garbage].
  4. A YEAR OF PROGRESS, supra note 1, at 1.
  5. McInerney, supra note 2.
  6. Catherine A. Kin, et. al, Globalization, Extended Producer Responsibility and the Problem of Discarded Computers in China: An Exploratory Proposal for Environmental Protection, 14 GEO. INT’L ENVTL. L. REV. 525, 530 (2002).
  7. See James Salzman, Sustainable Consumption and the Law, 27 ENVTL. L. 1243, 1274-75 (1997).
  8. See, e.g., Robert M. Sussman & Greg S. Slater, Domestic Legislation with Cross-Border Implications: International Trends in Product Take-Back Requirements, SB79 ALI-ABA 183, (1997).
  9. Salzman, supra note 7, at 1271.
  10. Id. at 1274.
  11. Notice published under Article 19(3) of Council Regulation No 17–Case 34.950–Eco-Emballages, 2000 OJ (C 227) 43 [hereinafter Eco-Emballages]; Steven P. Reynolds, The German Recycling Experiment and Its Lessons for United States Policy, 6 VILL. ENVTL. L.J. 43, 50 (1995).
  12. See, e.g., Reynolds, supra note 11, at 72.
  13. See Sussman & Slater, supra note 8, at 187-88.
  14. Id.; see also Salzman, supra note 7, at 1249 (describing Extended Producer Responsibility as “expanding the responsibility of actors to reduce products’ environmental impacts throughout the lifecycle”); Michael P. Vandenbergh, The Social Meaning of Command and Control, 20 VA. ENVTL. L.J.191 n.124 (2001) [hereinafter Vandenbergh, Social Meaning] (defining take-back requirements as requiring the manufacturer or importer of a consumer good to take the good back from the consumer at the end of its useful life).
  15. Sussman & Slater, supra note 8, at 183.
  16. See Salzman, supra note 7, at 1270.
  17. Id. at 1274.
  18. Sussman & Slater, supra note 8, at 187; see also Linda Roeder, Hazardous Waste: Roeder, Electronics Coalition Considers Plan to Charge Consumers for Recycling, DAILY ENV’T REP., 2003, at A3 (discussing the need for approval of a national take-back plan by Congress) [hereinafter Roeder, Electronics Coalition Considers].
  19. Salzman, supra note 7, at 1270.
  20. Id.
  21. Id.
  22. Id.
  23. Id.
  24. Id. at 1274.
  25. See id.
  26. See Linda Roeder, Hazardous Waste: Advocacy Group Recommendations Promote Manufacturer Responsibility, DAILY ENV’T REP., 2004.
  27. See Salzman, supra note 7, at 1274.
  28. Id.
  29. Id.
  30. Id. at 1270-71.
  31. Id. at 1277.
  32. Directive 2002/96/EC on Waste Electrical and Electronic Equipment (WEEE), 2003 O.J. (L 37) 46 [hereinafter Directive on WEEE].
  33. Id. art. 1.
  34. Id. art. 4.
  35. Id. art. 5.
  36. Id. art. 10.
  37. Directive 2002/95/EC on the Restriction of the Use of Certain Hazardous Substances in Electrical and Electronic Equipment, 2003 O.J. (L (37) 19 [hereinafter Hazardous Substances Directive].
  38. Id. art. 1. Such materials include lead, mercury, cadmium, hexavalent chromium, polybrominated biphenyls (PBB), or polybrominated diphenyl ethers (PBDE). Id.
  39. Id. art. 4.
  40. Council Directive 94/62/EC of December 1999 on packaging and packaging waste, 1994 O.J. (L 365) 37 [hereinafter European Packing Directive]; see also Amy Halpert, Note, Germany’s Solid Waste Disposal System: Shifting the Responsibility, 14 GEO. INT’L. ENVTL. L. REV. 135, 154 (2001). Web.
  41. See European Packaging Directive, supra note 40, at 14.
  42. Halpert, supra note 40, at 154.
  43. Id.; Jonathan Schneeweiss, Putting Packaging Waste in Its Place: The Case for Federal Legislation, 15 VA. ENVT’L L.J. 443, 456 (1995) (citing European Packaging Directive).
  44. Proposal for a Council Directive on end of life vehicles, 1997 O.J. (C 337) 40 [hereinafter Directive on Vehicles].
  45. Id. at Explanatory Memorandum part II.9.
  46. Id.
  47. Id. art. 5.
  48. Id. art. 6
  49. Id. art. 5.
  50. Schneeweiss, supra note 43, at 454.
  51. Id. at 455.
  52. Id. at 455-56 (citing European Packaging Directive).
  53. Reynolds, supra note 11, at 48 (citing Ordinance on the Avoidance of Packaging Waste (Verpacksungsverordnung) (1991)); Salzman, supra note 7, at 1271.
  54. Reynolds, supra note 11, at 48-49.
  55. Schneeweiss, supra note 43, at 463.
  56. Reynolds, supra note 11, at 50.
  57. European Packaging Directive, supra note 40.
  58. Reynolds, supra note 11, at 50.
  59. Id.
  60. Id. at 51.
  61. Id. at 51; Schneeweiss, supra note 43, at 463.
  62. Schneeweiss, supra note 43, at 463.
  63. Halpert, supra note 40, at 144.
  64. Reynolds, supra note 11, at 55.
  65. See Salzman, supra note 7, at 1274.
  66. Halpert, supra note 40, at 146.
  67. Id.
  68. Id. at 147.
  69. Id. at 153-54; see also European Packaging Directive, supra note 40.
  70. Halpert, supra note 40, at 153.
  71. See The Green Dot in Europe (n.d.). Web.
  72. Id.
  73. Halpert, supra note 40, at 154.
  74. Eco-Emballages, supra note 11.
  75. Id.
  76. Id.
  77. Id.
  78. Id; see also The Green Dot in Europe, supra note 71.
  79. See Eco-Emballages, supra note 11.
  80. Id.
  81. Id.
  82. Id.
  83. Id.
  84. Eco-Emballages, supra note 11.
  85. Id.
  86. Id.
  87. France to Require Manufacturers, Distributors, Importers to Recycle Tires, INT’L ENVTL. REP., 2003. Web.
  88. Id.
  89. Id.
  90. Lawrence J. Speer, France Publishes Licensing Rules for New Tire Recycling Program, 27 INT’L ENV’T REP. 9, 2004. The principal organization coordinating the implementation of French laws on tire recycling announced plans to levy a two to three percent recycling charge on all new tires. Id.
  91. France to Recycle Tires, supra note 87.
  92. Sussman & Slater, supra note 8, at 193. For example, in the 1990s the Swedish Parliament passed an “eco-cycle” law, requiring product manufacturers to take responsibility for disposing of their products in an environmentally friendly manner. David J. Hayes, Beyond Cradle to Grave, ENVTL. FORUM,14 (1993).
  93. Grass Roots Recycling Network, Computer TakeBack. Web.
  94. Solid Waste, 27 ENV’T REP. 1204, 1205 (1996).
  95. Computer TakeBack, supra note 93.
  96. Id.
  97. James E. Donnelly, Numbers Never Lie, But What Do They Say? A Comparative Look at Municipal Solid Waste Recycling in the United States and Germany, 15 GEO. INT’L. ENVTL. L. REY. 29, 39 (2002) (citing STATE RECYCLING LAWS UPDATE YEAR-END EDITION. (Raymond Communications, Inc.), at 42).
  98. MASS. ANN. LAWS ch. 21 [section] 52A (2001).
  99. Donnelly, supra note 97, at 39.
  100. Ann E. Carlson, Recycling Norms, 89 CAL. L. REV. 1231, 1264 (2001).
  101. See Donnelly, supra note 97, at 39; see also State of Garbage 1999, supra note 3, at 49, 52. For example, 37 states ban tires from landfills, 43 states ban car batteries, and other states ban motor oil. Id. at 40.
  102. Donnelly, supra note 97, at 40-41.
  103. Id.
  104. Id. at 41; see also Carlson, supra note 100, at 1266-68.
  105. Donnelly, supra note 97, at 41-42.
  106. Id. at 42.
  107. Id.
  108. Carlson, supra note 100, at 1265.
  109. Id. Typical curbside programs collect newspaper, bottles, and cans. Donnelly, supra note 97, at 44.
  110. State of Garbage 1999, supra note 3, at 64. Curbside programs have grown significantly in the last decade, from 1,042 in 1989 to 9,349 in 1999. Jim Glenn, State of Garbage in America, BIOCYCLE, at 48; State of Garbage 1999, supra note 3, at 63.
  111. Donnelly, supra note 97, at 44-45.
  112. Id. at 45.
  113. Id.
  114. See Jeffrey B. Wagenbach, The Bottle Bill: Progress and Prospects, 36 SYRACUSE L. REV. 761-62 (1985); see also Carlson, supra note 100, at 1266-1267. California developed a unique bottle bill system that requires manufacturers of beverages to pay $0.02 per container, which goes directly into the state recycling fund. Carlson, supra note 100, at 1267 n.143 (citing CAL. PUB. RES. CODE [subsections] 14501-14599). Consumers may return containers to a state redemption center for a refund of $0.025. Id. The state fund reimburses manufacturers for their expenses. Id.
  115. Sussman & Slater, supra note 8, at 203.
  116. Carolyn Whetzel, Hewlett-Packard, Dell Get High Marks for Recycling,, Take-Back Policies, DAILY ENV’T REP., 2004, at A6.
  117. Id.; Computer TakeBack, supra note 93.
  118. Whetzel, supra note 116.
  119. Sony to Spread Word to Shareholders of Policy Regarding Old Equipment, HAZARDOUS WASTE NEWS, 2000 [hereinafter Sony to Spread Word].
  120. Whetzel, supra note 116.
  121. Anne Morse, Letters, WASTE NEWS, 2002, at 8.
  122. Id.
  123. Vince Tuss, State Considers Bill to Ban Dumping of Discarded Electronic Items in Landfills, 32 ENV’T REP. 2322, 2322-23, 2001.
  124. Linda Roeder, Paying to Junk TVs, Monitors; Legislation: Bills Would Have California Collect Money at the Time of Sale to Cover Disposal, L.A. TIMES, 2002, at B1.
  125. Think Tanks Wrap-Up, UNITED PRESS INT’L, 2002 [hereinafter Think Tank].
  126. Id.
  127. Roeder, Electronics Coalition Considers, supra note 18.
  128. Id.
  129. Id.
  130. Linda Roeder, Hazardous Waste: Roeder, Industries Resolve to Continue Seeking Plan to Fund Electronic Waste Recycling, DAILY ENV’T REP., 2004, at A4.
  131. Roeder, Electronics Coalition Considers, supra note 18.
  132. Kin, supra note 6, at 536.
  133. See e.g. McInerney, supra note 2.
  134. See e.g. Reynolds, supra note 11 at 67. See generally Halpert, supra note 40 (discussing German environmental policy and using the German model to evaluate U.S. policy).
  135. Reynolds, supra note 11, at 67.
  136. Id.
  137. Id.
  138. Id.
  139. Id.
  140. Donnelly, supra note 97, at 48.
  141. Id. at 48-49.
  142. Reynolds, supra note 11, at 67 (describing in general terms what the author believes to be a popularly held assumption about American culture).
  143. See Marco Verweij, Why Is the River Rhine Cleaner Than the Great Lakes (Despite Looser Regulation)?, 34 LAW & SOCY REV. 1007, 1024-25 (2000).
  144. See generally id. (addressing comprehensive studies of U.S. and German environmental regulations and their successes as applied to those bodies of water).
  145. Id.
  146. Id.
  147. Id. at 1025.
  148. Id. (Verweij makes this assertion based on his own interviews, as seen in n.18.).
  149. See id. at 1027.
  150. Id. at 1029. (citing generally on exceptionalism DANIEL J. ELAZAR, COMMUNAL AND INDIVIDUAL LIBERTY IN SWISS FEDERALISM (Daniel J. Elazar, Special Issue of Publius 23, 1993); LOUIS HARTZ, THE LIBERAL TRADITION IN AMERICA (Brace & World 1955); SAMUEL P. HUNTINGTON, AMERICAN POLITICS: THE PROMISE OF DISHARMONY (Belknap Press 1981) [hereinafter HUNTINGTON]; SEYMOUR MARTIN LIPSET, CONTINENTAL DIVIDE: THE INSTITUTIONS AND VALUES OF THE U.S. AND CANADA (Transaction Publishers 1996); BYRON E. SHAFTER, IS AMERICA DIFFERENT? A NEW LOOK AT AMERICAN EXCEPTIONALISM (Byron E. Shafer ed., Oxford: Clarendon Press 1991); AARON WILDASVSKY, THE RISE OF RADICAL EGALITARIANISM (American University Press 1991)).
  151. Id. (quoting HUNTINGTON, at 56).
  152. Id.
  153. Id. at 1030-31.
  154. Id.
  155. Id.
  156. Id.
  157. Id. at 1032-33.
  158. Id. at 1033.
  159. Id.
  160. Id. at 1034.
  161. Id. at 1031-34.
  162. Id. at 1035.
  163. Id.
  164. Id.
  165. See id. at 1036.
  166. Id.
  167. Id.
  168. H.R. Krikke, et. al., Mixed Policies for Recovery and Disposal of Multiple-Type Consumer Products, 124 J. ENVTL. ENGINEERING 368, 368 (1998).
  169. See Reynolds, supra note 11, at 72.
  170. Id.
  171. See id.
  172. See Think Tank, supra note 125.
  173. Id.
  174. See id.
  175. Linda Roeder, Roeder, Industries Resolve to Continue Seeking Plan to Fund Electronic Waste Recycling, DAILY ENV’T REP., 2004, at A4 [hereinafter Roeder, Industries].
  176. See id.
  177. See id.
  178. See id.
  179. Stacy J. Silveira, Comment, The American Environmental Movement: Surviving Through Diversity, 28 B.C. ENVTL. AFF. L. REV. 497, 498 (2001).
  180. David B. Spence, Paradox Lost: Logic, Morality, and the Foundations of Environmental Law in the 21st Century, 20 COLUM. J. ENVTL. L. 145, 147 (1995).
  181. Vandenbergh, Social Meaning, supra note 14, at 198 (finding that individuals do not see their roles in creating environmental problems).
  182. Id. at 206.
  183. Id. at 106-07.
  184. See id. at 207.
  185. Spence, supra note 180, at 153.
  186. See Vandenbergh, Social Meaning, supra note 14, at 208.
  187. Bradley A. Harsch, Consumerism and Environmental Policy: Moving Past Consumer Culture, 26 ECOLOGY L.Q. 543, 551-52 (1999).
  188. Id. at 552.
  189. Id.
  190. Holly Doremus, Constitutive Law and Environmental Policy, 22 STAN. ENVTL. L.J. 295, 333 (2003).
  191. See Verweij, supra note 143, at 1025-26.
  192. Doremus, supra note 190, at 333.
  193. Carol M. Rose, Scientific Innovation and Environmental Protection: Some Ethical Considerations, 32 ENVTL. L. 755, 767.
  194. Id.
  195. Id.
  196. Doremus, supra note 190, at 319.
  197. Id.
  198. Id.
  199. Rose, supra note 193, at 746.
  200. Doremus, supra note 190, at 319-20.
  201. Id. at 320.
  202. Id.
  203. Id. at 321.
  204. Id.
  205. Id. at 322.
  206. Id. at 320.
  207. Id. at 329.
  208. Id.
  209. Id.
  210. Rose, supra note 193, at 759.
  211. Id.
  212. Id. at 760.
  213. Id. at 762.
  214. Vandenbergh, Social Meaning, supra note 14, at 197 (citing 1999 NEETF Survey).
  215. Id. at 197-98 (interpreting NEETF results).
  216. Id. (citing Richard H. Pildes & Cass R. Sunstein, Reinventing the Regulatory State, 62 U. CHI. L. REV. 1 (1995)).
  217. See id. at 198.
  218. Congressman Earl Blumenauer, Entrepreneurial Environmentalism: A New Approach for the New Millenium, 30 ENVTL. L. 1, 4 (2000).
  219. Id.
  220. Poll: 66% Say Env’t Can Be Balanced With Other Needs, GREENWIRE, 1996.
  221. Doremus, supra note 190, at 324.
  222. Id. at 325. Several terms, all based on this theory, describe this phenomenon, including: “free-riding,” collective action problem, tragedy of the commons, and public goods. See Carlson, supra note 100, at 1243-45, n.33.
  223. Id.
  224. Id.
  225. Id. at 326.
  226. Vandenbergh, Social Meaning, supra note 14, at 198.
  227. See Michael P. Vandenbergh, Beyond Elegance: A Testable Typology of Social Norms in Corporate Environmental Compliance, 22 STAN. ENVTL. L.J. 55. 64 (2003) [hereinafter Vandenbergh, Beyond Elegance].
  228. Id.
  229. Id.
  230. Rose, supra note 193, at 764.
  231. Id.
  232. Id.
  233. Chris Coggins, Waste Prevention–An Issue of Shared Responsibility for UK Producers and Consumers: Policy Options and Measurement, 32 RESOURCES, CONSERVATION & RECYCLING, 181, 183 (2001).
  234. Id.
  235. Id.
  236. Angela Ebreo & Joanne Vining, Motives as Predictors of the Public’s Attitudes Toward Solid Waste Issues, 25 ENVTL. MGMT. 153, (2000).
  237. Id. at 154.
  238. Id.
  239. Id. at 155, 168.
  240. Id. at 155.
  241. Carlson, supra note 100, at 1282, n.203.
  242. See Vandenbergh, Beyond Elegance, supra note 227, at 67.
  243. See id. at 67-68.
  244. Id.
  245. Id. at 69.
  246. Id. at 69-70.
  247. Id. at 73 (citing SHALOM H. SCHWARTZ, A NORMATIVE DECISION-MAKING MODEL OF ALTRUISM, IN ALTRUISM AND HELPING BEHAVIOR 189, 193-202 (Jacqueline Macauley & Leonard Berkowitz eds., 1970)).
  248. Id.
  249. Id. at 75 (citing Richard McAdams, The Origin, Development, and Regulation of Norms, 96 MICH. L. REV. 338, 408 (1997)).
  250. Id. at 74.
  251. See Spence, supra note 180, at 158.
  252. Id. at 159.
  253. Id.
  254. See Id. at 166 (stating that legal standards facilitate collective action on the part of businesses irrespective of penalties).
  255. Id. at 166.
  256. Id.
  257. Id.
  258. Bette K. Fishbein, Carpet Take-Back: EPR American Style, ENVTL. QUALITY MGMT., 2000, at 25, 26.
  259. Id. at 26.
  260. Id.
  261. Id.
  262. Roeder, Industries, supra note 175.
  263. Blumenauer, supra note 218, at 4-5.
  264. Joe Truini, Scrambled Circuits; E-waste Recycling Initiative Staggers; Pessimism Grows, WASTE NEWS, 2003, at 1 [hereinafter Truini, Scrambled Circuits].
  265. Id.
  266. Id.
  267. Id.
  268. Id.
  269. Id.
  270. Id.
  271. Blumenauer, supra note 218, at 5.
  272. Truini, Scrambled Circuits, supra note 264.
  273. Blumenauer, supra note 218, at 5. Environmental liability regimes can be politically unpopular. For example, in 2002 a Maryland House of Delegates committee rejected two environmental bins supported by the governor, which would have increased fines for water pollution and restricted the dumping of solid waste. State House Speaker Casper Taylor Jr. claimed the bills went too far, stating “I really think there is a limit on how far the environmental community can go and still maintain a good pro-business climate. There’s got to be a balance, a certain reasonableness in our approach.” See Maryland: State Delegates Kill 2 of Governor’s Enviro Bills, GREENWIRE, 2002.
  274. See Rossella Brevetti, U.S. High Tech Industry Critical of EU Laws on Hazardous Substances, Electric Waste, INT’L ENVTL. DAILY, 2003 (publishing criticisms of similar legislation in Europe by industry leaders).
  275. Truini, Scrambled Circuits, supra note 264.
  276. Id.
  277. Id.
  278. See Roeder, Industries, supra note 175 (reporting on an effort to consider financing for electronic waste recycling plan).
  279. Damon Franz, Enviro Policy: Feds’ Attitudes, Regulations are Obstacles to; State Innovation–GAO, GREENWIRE, 2002.
  280. Fishbein, supra note 258, at 32 (take-back programs in carpet industry).
  281. Id.
  282. Id. at 33-34.
  283. Roeder, Industries, supra note 175.
  284. Id.
  285. Donnelly, supra note 97, at 49.
  286. Id. (using glass bottles as an illustrative example).
  287. See id (driving costs may exceed benefit to environment).
  288. Id. at 51 (drawing lessons from industrial recycling in Germany).
  289. Id. at 52.
  290. Id.
  291. Salzman, supra note 7, at 1289.
  292. Id.; see also Roeder, Industries, supra note 175 (discussion of consumer lees plan).
  293. See Harsch, supra note 187, at 553 (discussion of “polluter pays” principle).
  294. Salzman, supra note 7, at 1289-90.
  295. Id. at 1290.
  296. Id.
  297. Id.; see also Fishbein, supra note 258, at 25-26; Sony to Spread Word, supra note 119; Whetzel, supra note 116.
  298. Alice P. Jacobsohn, Deleting E-Waste, WASTE AGE, 2003, at 6.
  299. Id.
  300. Id.
  301. Id.
  302. Id.
  303. Id.
  304. Salzman, supra note 7, at 1281.
  305. Fishbein, supra note 258, at 34.
  306. Id.
  307. Salzman, supra note 7, at 1286.
  308. Id.
  309. Id.
  310. Id.
  311. Id.
  312. Id.
  313. Id. at 1286-87.
  314. Id. at 1287.
  315. Id.
  316. Id.
  317. See generally 40 C.F.R. [section] 264.1 (2004) (standards for owners and operators of hazardous waste treatment, storage, and disposal facilities).
  318. See id. [subsections] 264.1-264.101 (EPA requirements and procedures for TSD’s).
  319. Linda Roeder, Agency to Continue Push for Recycling By Redefining Waste, Promoting Reuse, ENV’T REP., 2004, at S-14.
  320. Id. at S-14.
  321. Doremus, supra note 190, at 296.
  322. Id. at 297.
  323. Blumenauer, supra note 218, at 5.
  324. Id.
  325. Ebreo & Vining, supra note 236, at 166.
  326. Id.
  327. Id. at 156.
  328. Id. at 155.
  329. Carlson, supra note 100, at 1285.
  330. Id.
  331. Ebreo & Vining, supra note 236, at 155.
  332. Id.
  333. See Vandenbergh, Social Meaning, supra note 14, at 202.
  334. See Doremus, supra note 190, at 302.
  335. See id.
  336. Id.
  337. See id.
  338. Id. at 304.
  339. Id.
  340. Id. at 305 (offering as an example the public school system, mandated by law, which makes available what we regard as minimum training for individuals).
  341. See, e.g., id. at 304-05 (discussing the ways in which laws encourage development of particular capabilities). Applying Doremus’ theory, EPR laws would encourage manufacturers to develop products to be in compliance with the law.
  342. See e.g. Halpert, supra note 40, at 146.
  343. See Vandenbergh, Social Meaning, supra note 14, at 197.
  344. Reynolds, supra note 11, at 72.
  345. Doremus, supra note 190, at 378.
  346. See id.
  347. This is a lesson learned from the German system’s unrealistic goals. See Reynolds, supra note 11, at 72.
  348. Id. at 63.
  349. Id.
  350. See Schneeweiss, supra note 43, at 454-55.
  351. Coggins, supra note 233, at 183.
  352. Id. at 184.
  353. See Verweij, supra note 143, at 1020-21.
  354. See id.
  355. See Salzman, supra note 7, at 1289.
  356. See Harsch, supra note 187, at 551-52.
  357. See Verweij, supra note 143, at 1029.
  358. See Rose, supra note 193, at 767.
  359. See generally Spence, supra note 180, at 158-63 (discussing the impact of environmental values on American society).
  360. Vandenbergh, Social Meaning, supra note 14, at 198.
  361. Vandenbergh, Beyond Elegance, supra note 227, at 64 (discussing deterrence as principle rationale for federal environmental enforcement).
  362. See id. at 67-68 (describing an alternative conceptual framework to the standard deterrence model).
  363. Harsch, supra note 187, at 553.
  364. Eco-Emballages, supra note 11 at 6; Schneeweiss, supra note 43, at 463.
  365. Roeder, Industries, supra note 175.
  366. See Salzman, supra note 7, at 1274.
  367. Reynolds, supra note 11, at 69.
  368. Id.
  369. See id. at 67 (describing the problems with implementing a massive collection plan in a country with great distances between population centers and industrial facilities).
  370. Donnelly, supra note 97, at 42.
  371. See, e.g., Halpert, supra note 40, at 146.
  372. See Jacobsohn, supra note 298.
  373. Ebreo & Vining, supra note 236, at 154.
  374. See Doremus, supra note 190, at 302.
  375. See Hazardous Substances Directive, supra note 37.
  376. See Doremus, supra note 190, at 297.

Megan Short, J.D. Candidate, Vanderbilt University Law School, 2005; B.S. University of Arizona, 2002. Special thanks Professor Michael Vandenbergh for his contributions to the topic. Thanks also to the entire Journal staff for their work in editing this piece.

Print
Need an custom research paper on Paper Recycling: Environmental and Business Issues written from scratch by a professional specifically for you?
808 writers online
Cite This paper
Select a referencing style:

Reference

IvyPanda. (2024, April 21). Paper Recycling: Environmental and Business Issues. https://ivypanda.com/essays/paper-recycling-environmental-and-business-issues/

Work Cited

"Paper Recycling: Environmental and Business Issues." IvyPanda, 21 Apr. 2024, ivypanda.com/essays/paper-recycling-environmental-and-business-issues/.

References

IvyPanda. (2024) 'Paper Recycling: Environmental and Business Issues'. 21 April.

References

IvyPanda. 2024. "Paper Recycling: Environmental and Business Issues." April 21, 2024. https://ivypanda.com/essays/paper-recycling-environmental-and-business-issues/.

1. IvyPanda. "Paper Recycling: Environmental and Business Issues." April 21, 2024. https://ivypanda.com/essays/paper-recycling-environmental-and-business-issues/.


Bibliography


IvyPanda. "Paper Recycling: Environmental and Business Issues." April 21, 2024. https://ivypanda.com/essays/paper-recycling-environmental-and-business-issues/.

Powered by CiteTotal, easy reference maker
If you are the copyright owner of this paper and no longer wish to have your work published on IvyPanda. Request the removal
More related papers
Cite
Print
1 / 1